Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

122

description

 

Transcript of Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

Page 1: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing
Page 2: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

Christian Funke

Selected Essays in Empirical Asset Pricing

Page 3: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

GABLER EDITION WISSENSCHAFT

EBS ForschungSchriftenreihe der European Business School (EBS)International University · Schloss ReichartshausenHerausgegeben vonUniv.-Prof. Ansgar Richter, PhD

Band 69

Die European Business School (EBS) – gegründet im Jahr 1971– ist Deutschlands älteste private Wissenschaftliche Hoch-schule für Betriebswirtschaftslehre im Universitätsrang. DieserVorreiterrolle fühlen sich ihre Professoren und Doktoranden in Forschung und Lehre verpflichtet. Mit der Schriftenreihe präsentiert die European Business School (EBS) ausgewählteErgebnisse ihrer betriebs- und volkswirtschaftlichen Forschung.

Page 4: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

Christian Funke

Selected Essays in Empirical Asset PricingInformation Incorporationat the Single-Firm, Industry,and Cross-Industry Level

With a foreword by Prof. Dr. Lutz Johanning

GABLER EDITION WISSENSCHAFT

Page 5: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

Bibliographic information published by the Deutsche Nationalbibliothek The Deutsche Nationalbibliothek lists this publication in the Deutsche Nationalbibliografie;detailed bibliographic data are available in the Internet at http://dnb.d-nb.de.

Dissertation European Business School (EBS) Oestrich-Winkel, 2008

D1540

.

.

1. Aulage Dezember 19971st Edition 2008

All rights reserved© Gabler | GWV Fachverlage GmbH, Wiesbaden 2008

Editorial Office: Frauke Schindler / Britta Göhrisch-Radmacher

Gabler is part of the specialist publishing group Springer Science+Business Media.www.gabler.de

No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval systemor transmitted, mechanical, photocopying or otherwise without priorpermission of the copyright holder.

Registered and/or industrial names, trade names, trade descriptions etc. cited in this publica-tion are part of the law for trade-mark protection and may not be used free in any form or byany means even if this is not specifically marked.

Cover design: Regine Zimmer, Dipl.-Designerin, Frankfurt/MainPrinted on acid-free paperPrinted in Germany

ISBN 978-3-8349-1142-1

Page 6: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

V

Foreword

Research in empirical asset pricing has – fostered by the availability of new databases –

become an important field of research within the last three decades. This kind of re-

search contributes to the ongoing and exciting debate between the neoclassical and the

behavioral explanation of asset pricing and can help to better explain the evolvement of

asset prices in capital markets.

Research in empirical asset pricing requires multiple competences: a sound un-

derstanding of capital markets, market designs, trading processes, and asset pricing

models, a superior handling of large databases, and efficient programming skills. Chris-

tian Funke lives up to this challenge and his doctoral thesis comprises of three important

essays in empirical asset pricing.

In the first essay, Christian investigates the long term performance of rival com-

panies related to acquisition targets. He documents an underreaction of capital markets

to the information contained in M&A announcements. Following large rival gain events

due to positive information signaling and large rival loss events due to the negative

competitive effects of the transaction, he observes a return drift for up to 12 months

after the announcement.

The second essay documents a strong and prevalent drift in long-term industry

returns after M&A announcements. Specifically, industries that experience positive av-

erage announcement reactions continue to do well in the future, while industries that

experience negative average announcement reactions continue to do poorly. The evi-

dence suggests that capital markets underreact to the industry-wide information pro-

vided by merger announcements.

In the third essay, Christian documents return predictability across stocks, spe-

cifically from customers to their suppliers. He shows that for large positive (negative)

customer price change events supplier stock prices experience significantly positive

(negative) cumulative abnormal returns for up to 20 days after the event. However, the

Page 7: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

VI

major part of these returns arises in the first five days and he cannot find such return

predictability for the largest stocks and the most recent time period, indicating that capi-

tal markets are relatively efficient in incorporating extreme customer return shocks into

supplier stock prices.

I wish that researchers and other capital markets professionals will acknowledge

Christians Funke's contribution to the ongoing debate on asset pricing.

Johannisberg, April 2008 Prof. Dr. Lutz Johanning

Page 8: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

VII

Preface

“We don't receive wisdom; we must discover it for ourselves after a journey that

no one can take for us or spare us.” Marcel Proust (1871-1922)

Writing a doctoral thesis is never an easy or straightforward endeavor. I would not have

been able to complete this work without the help of many people whom I would like to

acknowledge here.

First, I would like to express my sincere gratitude to my doctoral supervisor Lutz

Johanning for his guidance and encouragement throughout the last three years. I owe

him much for the outstanding opportunities he made possible during my time as Re-

search Assistant at the Dean’s Office of Full-time Programmes and the Endowed Chair

of Asset Management at European Business School (EBS). Especially valuable was the

experience I gained by teaching lectures and case studies on risk management, asset

management, investments, and statistics at EBS and the opportunity to spend a semester

abroad in the PhD program of the Katz Graduate School of Business, University of

Pittsburgh. With regard to my semester abroad, I gratefully acknowledge financial sup-

port provided by the German Academic Exchange Service (DAAD) and the EBS De-

partment of Finance (Stiftung Unternehmensfinanzierung und Kapitalmärkte für den

Finanzstandort Deutschland).

Second, I would like to thank Dirk Schiereck for readily agreeing to provide the

second opinion on my thesis and providing helpful and constructive feedback during my

annual proposal defenses. Also, I would like to appreciate the valuable comments and

insights provided by Yakov Amihud from the Stern School of Business, New York

University, during his research visits to EBS.

Third, I am thankful for the exceptional support and help of my colleague and

friend Timo Gebken. He not only provided me with a vision for innovative empirical

research, a sounding board for research ideas, and a lot of valuable academic advice, but

Page 9: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

VIII

also became a good friend during my time at the Chair. In addition, my special appre-

ciation goes to my colleagues and friends Gaston Michel and Sebastian Werner, who

made my time at the Chair a memorable experience, both during and outside office

hours. I would like to thank them and Felix Zeidler for valuable comments and insights

which substantially enhanced this dissertation.

Fourth, I would like to thank all of my colleagues at the Endowed Chair of Asset

Management and the Endowed Chair of Banking and Finance for the fun times we had

on and off work. Also, I would like to thank my fellow doctoral students who formed

the “Underdocs United” soccer team together with me and brought it to some success in

Monday’s Soccerworld Mainz indoor league. The same appreciation goes to all my

friends and colleagues at EBS who joined and supported my newly founded soccer club

FC Altkönig e.V. Finally, I would like to thank Tobias Weigl for being an uncompli-

cated room mate during our PhD days (and nights) in Oestrich-Winkel, and Gerhard

Trautmann for our regular lunch meetings to talk about anything and everything.

Last, but definitely not least, I would like to thank my family and my fiancée

Julie. My parents and my brother always encouraged me and provided me with the free-

dom to pursue my goals. Without their continuous support, love, and patience I could

not have completed this dissertation. Finally, I am especially grateful to Julie, who not

only supported me when I worked long hours and weekends on this thesis, but also

made the tremendous effort to find and correct every single one of my English language

mistakes. Of course, any remaining errors are mine. Her support and love gave me the

necessary strength and motivation to finish this doctoral thesis. I dedicate this disserta-

tion to her and to my family, especially to my grandmother Gisela and to my grandfa-

ther Ralf, who sadly passed away before I could present this thesis to him.

Kronberg im Taunus, January 2008 Christian Funke

Page 10: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

IX

Overview

List of Tables and Figures........................................................................................... XIII List of Abbreviations ....................................................................................................XV List of Symbols ..........................................................................................................XVII

1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 11.1 Overview and General Research Objective ................................................... 1 1.2 Essay 1: Research Question and Main Findings ............................................ 3 1.3 Essay 2: Research Question and Main Findings ............................................ 5 1.4 Essay 3: Research Question and Main Findings ............................................ 6

2 Information Signaling and Competitive Effects of M&A: Long-Term Performance of Rival Companies ........................................................................ 92.1 Introduction.................................................................................................. 102.2 Related Literature......................................................................................... 132.3 Data and Methodology................................................................................. 152.4 Results .......................................................................................................... 242.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 36Appendix ............................................................................................................... 38

3 Predictability of Industry Returns After M&A Announcements................... 393.1 Introduction.................................................................................................. 403.2 Data and Methodology................................................................................. 433.3 Results .......................................................................................................... 483.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 65

4 Predictability of Supplier Returns After Large Customer Price Changes.... 674.1 Introduction.................................................................................................. 684.2 Related Literature......................................................................................... 714.3 Data and Methodology................................................................................. 754.4 Results .......................................................................................................... 834.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 96

5 Conclusion............................................................................................................ 99

References ................................................................................................................... 101

Page 11: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

XI

Table of Contents

List of Tables and Figures........................................................................................... XIII List of Abbreviations ....................................................................................................XV List of Symbols ..........................................................................................................XVII

1 Introduction........................................................................................................... 11.1 Overview and General Research Objective ................................................... 1 1.2 Essay 1: Research Question and Main Findings ............................................ 3 1.3 Essay 2: Research Question and Main Findings ............................................ 5 1.4 Essay 3: Research Question and Main Findings ............................................ 6

2 Information Signaling and Competitive Effects of M&A: Long-Term Performance of Rival Companies ........................................................................ 92.1 Introduction.................................................................................................. 102.2 Related Literature......................................................................................... 132.3 Data and Methodology................................................................................. 15

2.3.1 Data .................................................................................................. 15 2.3.2 Event Identification.......................................................................... 16 2.3.3 Long-Term Performance.................................................................. 21

2.4 Results .......................................................................................................... 24 2.4.1 Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Returns .................................................... 242.4.2 Calendar-Time Portfolios................................................................. 272.4.3 Size Groups ...................................................................................... 312.4.4 Cross-Sectional Regressions ............................................................ 33

2.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 36 Appendix ............................................................................................................... 38

3 Predictability of Industry Returns After M&A Announcements................... 393.1 Introduction.................................................................................................. 403.2 Data and Methodology................................................................................. 43

3.2.1 Daily Announcement Effects ........................................................... 433.2.2 Monthly Returns .............................................................................. 46

Page 12: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

XII

3.3 Results .......................................................................................................... 483.3.1 Industry Announcement Effects....................................................... 48

3.3.1.1 Persistence in Intra-Industry Effects ................................. 48 3.3.1.2 Predictability of Monthly Industry Returns ...................... 50

3.3.2 Industry Portfolio Investment Strategies.......................................... 52 3.3.2.1 Raw and Adjusted Returns................................................ 523.3.2.2 Subperiod Analysis ........................................................... 553.3.2.3 Size Groups ....................................................................... 563.3.2.4 Liquidity Effects ............................................................... 583.3.2.5 Strength of Intra-Industry Effects ..................................... 593.3.2.6 Three-Factor Risks ............................................................ 61

3.3.3 The Cross-Section of Individual Stock Returns............................... 63 3.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 65

4 Predictability of Supplier Returns After Large Customer Price Changes.... 674.1 Introduction.................................................................................................. 68 4.2 Related Literature......................................................................................... 71 4.3 Data and Methodology................................................................................. 75

4.3.1 Customer-Supplier Relationships .................................................. 75 4.3.2 Large Abnormal Customer Price Changes..................................... 76 4.3.3 Post-Event Abnormal Supplier Returns ......................................... 79

4.4 Results .......................................................................................................... 83 4.4.1 Large Abnormal Customer Price Changes..................................... 834.4.2 Contemporaneous Supplier Reactions ........................................... 854.4.3 Within- and Cross-Industry Effects ............................................... 864.4.4 Size Groups .................................................................................... 884.4.5 Time-Period Subsamples ............................................................... 904.4.6 Robustness Tests ............................................................................ 914.4.7 Cumulative Abnormal Return Regressions.................................... 93

4.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................... 96

5 Conclusion............................................................................................................ 99

References ................................................................................................................... 101

Page 13: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

XIII

List of Tables and Figures

Table 2.1: Annual Distribution of M&A Transactions and Average Rival Reactions19

Table 2.2: Annual Distribution of Rivals with Large Short-Term Reactions .............21

Table 2.3: Long-Term Rival Buy-and-Hold-Abnormal Returns.................................25

Table 2.4: Calendar-Time Portfolio Returns...............................................................28

Table 2.5: Calendar-Time Portfolio Three-Factor Alphas ..........................................30

Table 2.6: Long-Term Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Returns for Rival Size Groups.......32

Table 2.7: Cross-Sectional Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Return Regressions.................34

Table 3.1: Annual Distribution of M&A Transactions and Average Industry Announcement Effects ...............................................................................45

Table 3.2: Industry Summary Statistics ......................................................................47

Table 3.3: Industry Cumulative Abnormal Returns to M&A Announcements ..........49

Table 3.4: Monthly Industry Size and Book-to-Market Adjusted Returns .................51

Table 3.5: Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns...........................................................54

Table 3.6: Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns for Time-Period Subsamples ............55

Table 3.7: Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns for Size-Quintiles .............................57

Table 3.8: Robustness of Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns ...................................59

Table 3.9: Industry Portfolio Three-Factor Alphas .....................................................62

Table 3.10: Fama/MacBeth Regressions for Individual Stock Returns ........................65

Table 4.1: Summary Statistics.....................................................................................78

Table 4.2: Annual Descriptive Statistics .....................................................................82

Table 4.3: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers after Customer Return Shocks ................84

Table 4.4: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers Conditional on Initial Reaction ...............86

Table 4.5: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers Within and Across Industries ..................87

Table 4.6: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers for Different Size Groups........................89

Table 4.7: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers for Different Sample Periods...................91

Table 4.8: Robustness Tests ........................................................................................92

Table 4.9: Cross-Sectional Cumulative Abnormal Return Regressions .....................94

Page 14: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

XIV

Figure 2.1: Historical Distribution of Rival Cumulative Abnormal Returns .............. 20

Figure 2.2: Event-Time Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Rival Returns ............................... 26

Page 15: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

XV

List of Abbreviations

ADR American Depository Receipt

AR Abnormal Return

BHAR Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Return

B/M Book-to-Market

CAPM Capital Asset Pricing Model

CAR Cumulative Abnormal Return

CRSP Center for Research in Securities Prices

FASB Financial Accounting Standards Board

GVKEY Compustat Unique Firm Identifier

M&A Mergers and Acquisitions

N Number of Observations

NYSE New York Stock Exchange

PERMNO CRSP Unique Security Identifier

PPE Property, Plant, and Equipment

REIT Real Estate Investment Trust

SBI Shares of Beneficial Interest

S.D. Standard Deviation

SDC Securities Data Company

SFAS Statements of Financial Accounting Standards

SIC Standard Industrial Classification

Page 16: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

XVII

List of Symbols

pa Time-series regression intercept for portfolio p

tiAR , Abormal return of firm i on day t

pb Time-series regression factor loading on market factor for portfolio p

],[, TtiBHAR Buy and hold abnormal return for firm i from point in time t until T

]20,1[,iBHAR Buy and hold abnormal return for firm i and 20-day post-event window

]20,1[,iCAR Cumulative abnormal return for firm i and 20-day post-event window

]2,2[CAR Cumulative abnormal return over 5-day event window

1,tiCAR Average 5-day cumulative abnormal return of equal-weighted industry

portfolio i in the prior month t-1

tjCUSTAR , Abnormal return of customer j on event day t

tp, Time-series regression error-term for portfolio p in month t

ti , Cross-sectional regression error-term for event i at point in time t

ph Time-series regression factor loading on HML for portfolio p

HML Fama and French (1993) value factor (high minus low)

tfR , Risk-free return over time interval t

tiR , Return of firm i over time interval t

tjR , Return of control firm j over time interval t

tmR . Return of equal-weighted CRSP market index over time interval t

tsR , Return of size quintile s over time interval t

tpR , Return of event portfolio p at month t after portfolio formation 2R Regression coefficient of determination (R squared)

ps Time-series regression factor loading on SMB for portfolio p

SMB Fama and French (1993) size factor (small minus big)

tiSUPPAR , Abnormal return of supplier i on event day t

tiSUPPSIZE , Natural logarithm of supplier i market value of equity on event day t

tjiWITHININD ,, Dummy equal to one if supplier i and customer j in the same industry

Page 17: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

1

1 Introduction

1.1 Overview and General Research Objective

This doctoral thesis comprises three essays that address selected issues in empirical as-

set pricing. All three essays conduct original empirical research using U.S. capital mar-

ket data. The first two essays both investigate the importance of mergers and acquisi-

tions (M&A) for stock prices. The first essay (Chapter 2) focuses on the single-firm

level and investigates the long-term performance of rival firms directly affected by

M&A transactions. Following a similar intuition, the second essay (Chapter 3) takes an

industry perspective and examines the long-term performance of industry portfolios

depending on the impact of M&A on the firms in the industry. Finally, the third essay

(Chapter 4) focuses on the cross-industry level as it follows explicit economic links be-

tween firms across industries and investigates the information transmission from cus-

tomer stock prices to supplier stock prices.

Although different in focus and approach, all three essays contribute to the main

challenge of developing a better understanding of a central asset pricing issue: how effi-

ciently do capital markets incorporate new information into the stock price discovery

process. Are capital markets efficient or can we empirically observe violations of mar-

ket efficiency in the information incorporation process?

This question is a central issue in the asset pricing literature. In general, accord-

ing to Campbell (2000) (p. 1516), “…asset pricing is concerned with the sources of risk

and the economic forces that determine the rewards for bearing risk”. I focus on specific

research questions related to a particular area in asset pricing, i.e., the cross-sectional

structure of stock returns. This topic has generated a lot of research interest given the

discovery of several apparent ‘anomalies’ in the cross-section of stock returns, which

cannot be explained by the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964),

Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966). The most prominent cross-sectional anomalies are

the small-firm effect (Banz (1981)), the value effect (Basu (1983), Rosenberg, Reid and

Page 18: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

2

Lanstein (1985), Fama and French (1992)), which is related to the contrarian effect (De

Bondt and Thaler (1985)), and finally, the momentum effect (Jegadeesh and Titman

(1993)). In his extensive review of the asset pricing literature, Campbell (2000) notes

several explanation for these anomalies (pp. 1527-1528):

The first and most conservative interpretation is that they are entirely spurious, the result of ‘data

snooping’ that has found accidental patterns in historical data. (…) A second view is that the anoma-

lies result from the inability of a broad stock index to proxy for the market portfolio return. (…) A

third view is that the anomalies provide genuine evidence against the CAPM but not against a

broader rational model in which there are multiple risk factors. (…) A fourth view is that the anoma-

lies do not reflect any type of risk but are ‘mistakes’ that disappear once market participants become

aware of them. (…) The most radical view is that the anomalies reflect enduring psychological biases

that lead investors to make irrational forecasts.

A lot of research has been undertaken in the last years to answer these issues, but

essentially the question of how to best price the cross-section of stock returns has re-

mained largely unresolved. In the last years the ‘radical view’ of behavioral finance has

generated the most attention. In his review of this field, Hirshleifer (2001) argues (p.

1534) “… that the central task of asset pricing is to examine how expected returns are

related to risk and to investor misevaluation”, a view which is opposed to the one repre-

sented by efficient markets proponents such as Fama (1998) and Campbell (2000). In

general, researchers in the behavioral finance field argue that there are a variety of psy-

chological reasons for the mispricing of assets. Therefore, the argument goes, equilib-

rium prices reflect the weighted average of rational and irrational traders, given the fact

that limits of arbitrage exist which prevent rational arbitrageurs from exploiting mispri-

cing to the full extent (Shleifer and Vishny (1997)). In addition, Hirshleifer (2001) notes

that (p. 1539):

(…a) possible reason for persistent mispricing is that some relevant pieces of public information are

ignored or misused by everyone. This can occur either because the signals are obscurely located or

because our shared model of the world is just not sophisticated enough to make their relevance clear.

This intuition provides the motivation and starting point for my research. In this

doctoral thesis, I focus on the information incorporation process for related firms, i.e.

firms only indirectly affected by the “pieces of public information” in question. This is

Page 19: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

3

an important topic, as so far researchers have focused on investigating the information

incorporation process for firms directly affected by the information at hand. However,

major corporate events, such as M&A, also have important consequences for rival firms

and the whole industry. So far, mainly the short-term effects of these events for rival

companies have been investigated, i.e., their long-term consequences and the question

of market efficiency in the information incorporation process have been neglected, an

issue which I investigate in the first two essays of this doctoral thesis. In addition, re-

cently cross-industry links have generated increasing attention, as they appear to repre-

sent examples of relevant pieces of information which are often ignored. Therefore, I

complete this doctoral thesis with a third essay examining the importance of economic

links between customers and suppliers in the information incorporation process.

Overall, the research objective of this doctoral thesis is to improve our under-

standing of the efficiency of capital markets by providing new evidence on the informa-

tion incorporation process at the single-firm, industry, and cross-industry level.

1.2 Essay 1: Research Question and Main Findings

The first essay entitled “Information Signaling and Competitive Effects of M&A: Long-

Term Performance of Rival Companies” investigates the long-term performance of rival

firms related to acquisition targets.

The intra-industry effects of M&A announcements are based on two opposing

effects: positive information-signaling regarding future takeover activity and negative

competitive effects of the transaction. The empirical evidence based on short-term event

studies shows that rival firms gain at the M&A announcement. Hence, the positive in-

formation signaling effects of the deal outweigh the negative competitive effects. How-

ever, long-term studies regarding the transaction success of the merging firms show that

prices do not fully adjust to the information implied by M&A transactions. Given the

evidence on the long-term underperformance of acquiring firms, it is straightforward to

ask whether we can observe a similar underreaction of capital markets to the informa-

tion contained in M&A announcements for the case of rival companies. So far research-

Page 20: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

4

ers have not investigated the long-term effects of M&A announcements on rivals.

Therefore, the objective of the first essay is to fill this research gap and provide empiri-

cal evidence on the long-term wealth effects of corporate acquisitions on directly af-

fected rival firms. This question is important to understand how capital markets incor-

porate the information contained in M&A announcements into stock prices.

Research Question 1:

What are the long-term wealth effects of corporate acquisitions on directly affected ri-

val firms? Are the positive information-signaling effects and negative competitive ef-

fects of M&A transactions efficiently incorporated into rival stock prices?

I examine this question using a sample of 2,511 deals announced between Janu-

ary 1, 1985 and December 31, 2005. Based on return correlations to the target and the

short-term reaction around the deal announcement, I identify rival firms clearly affected

by the transaction due to the positive information-signaling effects and the negative

competitive effects of the transaction. Overall, I investigate samples of 6,138 large rival

gain events and 5,408 large rival loss events.

I find that rivals with large gains at the announcement of a deal due to positive

information-signaling experience significantly positive buy-and-hold-abnormal returns

for a year after the announcement, while rivals suffering large losses due to the negative

competitive effects of a M&A transaction experience significantly negative returns over

the same horizon. My results are robust to the choice of methodology to calculate long-

term performance, alternative approaches such as the calendar-time portfolio method

using size and book-to-market matched control firms or a Fama and French (1993)

three-factor asset pricing model show similar findings. This result indicates that capital

markets underreact to the information contained in M&A transactions for the stock price

performance of rivals, a result which fits well into the literature on underreaction of

capital markets to new information (Frazzini (2006), Jackson and Johnson (2006),

Zhang (2006)).

Page 21: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

5

1.3 Essay 2: Research Question and Main Findings

The second essay entitled “Predictability of Industry Returns After M&A Announce-

ments” investigates long-term industry returns after M&A announcements.

As mentioned above, overall, researchers find that rival firms gain in short-term

windows around M&A announcements. In a recent study, Funke et al. (2008) show that

these positive industry reactions are not pervasive over time. At the beginning of an

industry-wide consolidation process intra-industry effects are significantly positive.

However, due to increasing competition, intra-industry effects decrease steadily and

become negative at the end of such a consolidation process. Hence, time-varying com-

petitive effects of M&A activity, depending on time-varying industry structure, are re-

sponsible for a significant difference in intra-industry reactions over time. However, as

industry structure and, therefore, the competitive effects of M&A activity change rela-

tively slowly over time, their evidence suggests a certain persistence in average monthly

intra-industry announcement reactions. As short-horizon intra-industry effects directly

impact industry returns, such a persistence may also influence long-term industry per-

formance. To the author’s best knowledge, long-term industry returns after merger an-

nouncements have not yet been studied. Therefore, the research objective of the second

essay of this doctoral thesis is to investigate whether there are systematic differences in

industry returns after M&A announcements depending on the initial intra-industry ef-

fects of the deal.

Research Question 2:

Are there systematic differences in industry returns after M&A announcements depend-

ing on the initial intra-industry effects of the deal?

Using a dataset of 16,483 transactions that occur within one of 20 industries be-

tween 1985 and 2002, I investigate whether the average industry reaction in previous

periods affects the intra-industry effects of transaction announcements in later periods. I

find that this is indeed the case: the cumulative abnormal return (CAR) at the an-

nouncement of an M&A transaction depends on the average reaction to merger an-

nouncements in the same industry in the previous month. Based on this result, I look at

Page 22: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

6

monthly industry returns after merger announcements. Paralleling the results for CARs,

I find that returns depend on the average industry announcement reaction in the previ-

ous month.

Therefore, the evidence indicates that the industry-wide information provided by

merger announcements does not seem to be incorporated into stock prices immediately.

Industry M&A investment strategies, which buy positively reacting industries and sell

negatively reacting industries, appear profitable even after controlling for size and book-

to-market effects in returns. In robustness tests, I find that profitability has strengthened

over time, that the effect seems to exist also for the largest stocks, and that an alternative

risk-adjustment using the Fama and French (1993) three-factor asset pricing model can-

not explain the returns of the industry portfolio investment strategies. In addition, Fama-

McBeth regressions show that the average industry CAR of the previous month is sig-

nificantly related to individual stock returns of firms in that industry.

1.4 Essay 3: Research Question and Main Findings

The third essay entitled “Predictability of Supplier Returns After Large Customer Price

Changes” investigates return predictability across stocks, specifically from customers to

their suppliers. Limited investor attention (investor inattention) and the consequences

for information processing in capital markets have recently generated increasing interest

in the asset pricing literature. In a new paper Cohen and Frazzini (2006) examine eco-

nomically linked firms and document widespread cross-asset return predictability in

U.S. capital markets. They conclude that investors do not take into account ex-ante

available and often longstanding customer-supplier relationships due to their limited

attention, so that prices of supplier firms have a predictable lag in updating to new in-

formation about its customer firms.

However, Cohen and Frazzini (2006) focus on return predictability using

monthly data and do not investigate short-run effects on the daily level. A short-term

event study approach provides an ideal ground to test limited investor attention: if we

can observe supplier return predictability after extreme attention-grabbing customer

Page 23: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

7

price changes, then we can reasonably assume a violation of market efficiency due to

investor inattention to relevant, publicly available information. However, if we can find

no or limited evidence of supplier return predictability after such large customer price

changes, we can conclude that investor inattention to customer information is restricted

to the smaller price changes studied by Cohen and Frazzini (2006) at the monthly hori-

zon. Additionally, a short-term based investigation on how long it takes for customer

stock return information to be incorporated into supplier stock prices can provide valu-

able insights into the information incorporation process of capital markets.

Research Question 3:

3.1: Do we observe supplier return predictability as documented by Cohen and Frazz-

ini (2006) also on a daily basis in an event study framework using extreme atten-

tion-grabbing customer price changes?

3.2: How long does it take, exactly, for customer stock return information to be incor-

porated into supplier stock prices?

Using daily stock returns from 1981 to 2004, I investigate abnormal supplier

stock returns after large abnormal customer price changes, i.e., a daily customer abnor-

mal stock return three standard deviations or more from the mean. I show that for large

positive (negative) customer price change events supplier stock prices experience sig-

nificantly positive (negative) CARs for up to 20 days after the event. However, the ma-

jor part of these returns arises in the first five days after the event. In addition, I show

that if there is a large positive (negative) contemporaneous supplier reaction to a posi-

tive (negative) large customer price change, markets seem to have already incorporated

all information immediately and no post-event supplier drift can be discerned. However,

if there is no reaction or even a negative (positive) reaction to a positive (negative) large

customer price change, I document a drift in supplier stock prices in the same direction

as the customer event. Sometimes, investors seem to shift their limited attention not

immediately to this customer stock return information and, therefore, incorporate it only

slowly into supplier prices.

Page 24: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

9

2 Information Signaling and Competitive Effects of M&A:

Long-Term Performance of Rival Companies

Abstract

In this essay, I investigate the long-term performance of rival companies related to ac-

quisition targets. Using a sample of 2,511 deals from 1985 to 2005, I document an un-

derreaction of capital markets to the information contained in M&A announcements.

Following 6,138 large rival gain events due to positive information signaling and 5,408

large rival loss events due to the negative competitive effects of the deal, I find a return

drift for up to 12 months after the announcement. Hence, my results indicate that capi-

tal markets do not immediately incorporate the effects of M&A announcements into ri-

val stock prices.

I thank my co-authors Timo Gebken and Lutz Johanning, as well as Gaston Michel, Julie Ann Ng, Sebastian Werner, and Felix Zeidler for valuable comments and insights. I am also grateful for the input of workshop participants at EBS and WHU. Any remaining errors are mine.

Page 25: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

10

2.1 Introduction

Mergers and acquisitions are important corporate events. With regard to the wealth ef-

fects of M&A, evidence based on short-term event studies shows that target sharehold-

ers gain significantly from acquisitions, while acquiring firm shareholders lose or, at

most, break even around M&A announcements. However, long-term studies show that

prices do not fully adjust to the information implied by M&A transactions. Agrawal,

Jaffe and Mandelker (1992) document significantly negative long-term abnormal re-

turns to acquiring firms. These results are confirmed in later studies by Loughran and

Vijh (1997) and Rau and Vermaelen (1998).

Besides measuring the performance of the merging firms, researchers also exam-

ine the wealth effects of M&A on other firms from the same industry. The intra-industry

effects of M&A announcements are based on two opposing effects: positive information

signaling regarding future takeover activity and negative competitive effects of the

transaction. Overall, researchers find that rival firms gain at the M&A announcement.

Hence, the positive information signaling effects of the deal outweigh the negative

competitive effects (Eckbo (1983), Eckbo (1985), Song and Walkling (2000), Fee and

Thomas (2004) and Shahrur (2005)).

However, so far no studies exist that examine the long-term stock price perform-

ance of related rivals. Given the findings on significant abnormal long-term perform-

ance for acquiring firms, it is straightforward to ask whether we can observe a similar

underreaction of capital markets to the information contained in M&A announcements

for the stock prices of related firms. Therefore, the objective of this essay is to fill this

research gap and provide empirical evidence on the long-term wealth effects of corpo-

rate acquisitions on directly affected rival firms. This question is important to under-

stand how capital markets incorporate the information contained in M&A announce-

ments into stock prices.

I examine this question using a sample of 2,511 deals which have a minimum

transaction value of $100 million and are announced between January 1, 1985 and De-

cember 31, 2005. Based on return correlations measured over a year prior to the an-

nounced transaction, I identify the 30 most closely related rivals of each target firm.

Page 26: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

11

Next, I determine subsets of these related rivals by measuring the short-term reaction

around the deal announcement: I am interested in large positive or negative rival reac-

tions due to the positive information-signaling or negative competitive effects, respec-

tively, of the transactions. I select the rival events based on a combination of an absolute

percentage cut-off and a relative standard-deviation based requirement. That is, a short-

term absolute rival CAR of 5% (10%) is deemed to be a large (very large) return event,

if it is at least two standard deviations from zero. Overall, I investigate samples of 6,138

large rival gain events and 5,408 large rival loss events, where rivals, on average, ex-

perience absolute abnormal returns of roughly 10.6% in a five-day window around the

transaction announcement.

After controlling for the size and book-to-market effects using matching firms, I

find that rivals with large gains at the announcement of a deal due to positive informa-

tion-signaling (‘gaining rivals’) experience significantly positive buy-and-hold-

abnormal returns (BHAR) of 2.844% for a year after the announcement, while rivals

suffering large losses due to the negative competitive effects of a M&A transaction

(‘losing rivals’) experience significantly negative long-term returns of 8.146%. The dif-

ference between the two samples of 10.990% is highly statistically significant. When I

investigate very large return events, the BHAR difference between heavily gaining and

heavily losing rivals becomes even larger at 17.509% over 12 months. This finding in-

dicates that capital markets underreact to the information contained in M&A transac-

tions for the stock price performance of rivals, a result which fits well into the literature

on underreaction of capital markets to new information (Frazzini (2006), Jackson and

Johnson (2006), Zhang (2006)).

I document the robustness of my results by using an alternative methodology:

the calendar-time portfolio approach. A long-short portfolio with a long investment in

gaining rivals and a short investment in losing rivals earns an average monthly raw re-

turn of 0.629% (7.55% annualized) and an average monthly size and book-to-market

adjusted return of 0.638% (7.66% annualized) over the 12-month horizon, both highly

statistically significant. Using the Fama and French (1993) three-factor asset pricing

model as an alternative return adjustment method results in an average monthly alpha

Page 27: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

12

for the long-short portfolio of 0.726% (8.71% annualized), also highly statistically sig-

nificant. Overall, the results indicate that capital markets do not immediately incorpo-

rate the positive information signaling and negative competitive effects of M&A an-

nouncement into rival stock prices resulting in a return drift of up to a year after the

event.

Next, I document the impact of rival size on the observed long-term return drift.

Only micro-cap gaining rivals smaller than the 20th NYSE market capitalization percen-

tile experience significantly positive long-term returns: their 12-month post-event

BHAR is a statistically significant 8.548%. Small gaining rivals (between the 20th and

50th percentile) and big gaining rivals (above the 50th percentile) experience positive but

insignificant BHARs of 3.051% and 1.049%, respectively. This concurs with the con-

jecture that positive information signaling is more important for the smallest rivals: they

face a higher takeover likelihood and, therefore, experience a larger post-event drift.

However, for losing rivals, there is no discernible impact of rival size: the micro-cap,

small, and big firm subsamples earn comparable negative 12-month BHARs of 7.136%,

10.086%, and 7.345%, respectively.

Finally, I employ cross-sectional BHAR regressions in order to better understand

the drivers of the return drift. However, the regressions do not paint a precise picture of

the long-term BHARs to rivals. Further research into the underlying causes of the large

rival return events, i.e., positive information signaling and negative competitive effects

of M&A, is warranted in order to better understand the underreaction of capital markets

and the ensuing return predictability.

The remainder of this essay is structured as follows. Section 2.2 discusses the

findings of the related literature. Section 2.3 introduces the data and methodology used

in the empirical investigations. Section 2.4 presents the empirical results and Section 2.5

concludes.

Page 28: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

13

2.2 Related Literature

Many financial researchers have addressed the question of the wealth effects of M&A.

In general, they find that target shareholders gain significantly from acquisitions, while

acquiring firm shareholders lose or, at most, break even around M&A announcements.

The evidence is usually based on event studies using short-term event windows around

the announcement date and assumes that prices fully adjust to the expected efficiency

gains from acquisitions.1

Following these short-term event studies, some researchers have examined the

assumption of market efficiency by measuring the long-term performance following

acquisitions. Agrawal, Jaffe and Mandelker (1992) show that acquiring firms experience

significantly negative abnormal returns over a five-year post-merger period. Loughran

and Vijh (1997) document that cash bidders experience significantly positive abnormal

returns in the three to five years following a transaction announcement, although ac-

quirers experience negative long-term returns on average. Rau and Vermaelen (1998)

show that the long-term underperformance of acquiring firms is predominantly caused

by the poor post-acquisition performance of low book-to-market “glamour” firms.2

Researchers do not only examine the transaction success of the merging firms,

but also extensively investigate how other firms in the same industry are affected by the

transaction. The intra-industry effects of an acquisition are essentially based on two

factors. Firstly, rival firms may benefit from the positive information-signaling effect of

a transaction regarding future takeover activity in the industry. Secondly, rivals may be

hurt by the competitive effects of the M&A announcements due to increased competi-

tion from the newly merged firms. Overall, researchers have found that the positive in-

formation signaling effects outweigh the negative competitive effects of M&A transac-

1 The early literature is summarized in Jensen and Ruback (1983) and Jarrell, Brickley and Netter (1988). More recent evidence on the determinants of acquiring firm abnormal returns includes Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002), Mitchell, Pulvino and Stafford (2004), Moeller, Schlingemann and Stulz (2004), Masulis, Wang and Xie (2007), and Moeller, Schlingemann and Stulz (2007).

2 Other studies documenting the long-term underperformance of acquiring firms include Asquith (1983), Loderer and Martin (1992) and Agrawal, Jaffe and Mandelker (1992). The literature on long-term performance after M&A announcement is reviewed in Andrade, Mitchell and Stafford (2001).

Page 29: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

14

tions. For example, Eckbo (1983) and Eckbo (1985) find positive intra-industry effects

around the announcement of horizontal mergers. In a more extensive study, Song and

Walkling (2000) stress the importance of positive information-signaling effects due to

the increased takeover likelihood and document positive abnormal returns for rivals of

the target in their sample of horizontal and non-horizontal deals. More recently, Fee and

Thomas (2004) and Shahrur (2005) also show that competitors experience positive

stock market effects at the announcement of horizontal deals.3

Nevertheless, so far researchers have only investigated the short-term effects of

M&A announcements on rival companies. Given the evidence on the long-term under-

performance of acquiring firms, it is straightforward to ask whether we can observe a

similar underreaction of capital markets to the information contained in M&A an-

nouncements for the case of rival companies. To the author’s best knowledge this issue

has not been examined so far. Hence, in this essay I address the question of whether

capital markets efficiently incorporate the implications from M&A transactions into

competitors’ stock prices or whether we are able to observe any abnormal long-run re-

turns for rivals of the target company.

In general, besides the M&A literature, this essay fits into the extensive body of

evidence examining long-run stock returns following various kinds of corporate events,

such as earnings announcements (Bernard and Thomas (1989)), IPOs (Loughran and

Ritter (1995)), SEOs (Spiess and Affleck-Graves (1995)), share repurchases (Ikenberry,

Lakonishok and Vermaelen (1995)), dividend initiations and omissions (Michaely,

Thaler and Womack (1995)), stock splits (Ikenberry, Rankine and Stice (1996)),

spinoffs (Desai and Jain (1999)), debt offerings (Spiess and Affleck-Graves (1999)), or

R&D increases (Eberhart, Maxwell and Siddique (2004)). I extend this literature in an

important aspect by examining the long-term consequences of the corporate event for

related companies. In a recent study, Massa, Rehman and Vermaelen (2007) investigate

the information which open-market share repurchase announcements provide about the

3 However, Shahrur (2005) shows that rivals only gain significantly at the announcement of value-increasing transactions. Value-decreasing acquisitions are accompanied by negative wealth effects to the competitors.

Page 30: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

15

competitors of the repurchasing firms. In the course of their investigation, they also ana-

lyze the implications for rival firm stock price performance in the post-announcement

period. In this essay, I study the consequences of M&A announcements for long-

horizon rival returns. This topic is of particular interest: acquisitions arguably form the

most important type of corporate events, but the long-term performance of rivals has not

been investigated so far.

2.3 Data and Methodology 2.3.1 Data

Firstly, my data of mergers and acquisitions are from the Thomson One SDC Platinum

Database.4 I consider all deals that were announced between January 1, 1985 and De-

cember 31, 2005, which have a transaction value of at least $100 million and where the

acquirer is seeking to purchase at least 50% of shares. In addition, I require both ac-

quirer and target firm to be publicly listed U.S. companies, excluding foreign acquirers

and private firms. This results in an initial sample of 2,836 deals. I assign each transac-

tion to one of 12 industry sectors5 based on the target’s SIC code.6

Secondly, my stock return data are from CRSP. I only use stocks identified as

common equity (share code 10 and 11), excluding all certificates, ADRs, SBIs, REITs,

etc. In order to minimize the influence of market microstructure effects and to ensure

that the results are not driven by the tiniest micro-cap stocks, I exclude all firms which

have a closing stock price of less than 5$ and/or which have a market value of equity

4 The mergers and acquisitions section (SDC Platinum) of the Thomson One Banker Database was formerly known as the Securities Data Company’s (SDC) U.S. Mergers and Acquisitions Database.

5 As industry sector definitions I use the most recent version of the 12 industry portfolios defined by Fama and French (1997). I thank Ken French for providing the data on his website. The 12 industries are consumer nondurables, consumer durables, manufacturing, energy, chemicals, business equip-ment, telecom, utilities, wholesale and retail, healthcare, finance, and other.

6 I use target SIC codes from CRSP, which allows for time-series variation in industry classification. However, I can report that all our main results remain qualitatively and quantitatively similar if I use the SIC code as recorded by Thomson.

Page 31: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

16

below the 5th market capitalization percentile of NYSE stocks in the month before the

M&A announcement.7

Finally, my accounting data are from the annual Compustat files. Following the

usual practice in the asset pricing literature based on Fama and French (1992), I match

accounting variables for fiscal year-ends in year t 1 with CRSP returns from July of

year t to June of year t+1. Detailed definitions of the variables can be found in the ap-

pendix of this chapter.

2.3.2 Event Identification

I am interested in investigating the abnormal long-term return of rivals that experience

heavy positive information signaling effects or heavy competitive effects at the an-

nouncement of a transaction. In the course of the investigation, the rival identification

approach is as follows. I identify a set of potential target rivals based on the industry

classification of each transaction. Then, I narrow down this relatively broad set of firms

by calculating the return correlation of each potential rival with the target.8 For the ini-

tial analysis, I define the 30 firms as the rivals of the target which have the highest cor-

relation measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction.9 In

addition, I impose a minimum return correlation of 0.15 before I classify a firm as a

7 I thank Kenneth French for providing the NYSE breakpoints on his website. I can report that my findings are not sensitive to these exclusions.

8 Such a correlation-based approach to find the most related rivals is also used by Akhigbe and Martin (2000). I base my approach on a broad industry classification using 12 industry sectors (see footnote 5), as I rely on the correlation to clearly identify related rivals and want to avoid reducing the pool of potential rival firms too much by using a narrow industry definition, such as the 48 Fama and French (1997) industries.

9 In the following analysis I focus on results using the 30 most-correlated rivals to guarantee a suffi-cient sample size for the empirical investigations involving large return events. However, I can report that results are qualitatively and quantitatively similar using only the 10 or 20 most correlated rivals.

Page 32: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

17

rival.10 The sample is reduced to 2,511 deals, as I exclude all deals where the target did

not have stock returns for the correlation-estimation window.11

To identify those rivals that experience heavy positive information-signaling ef-

fects or heavy negative competitive effects, I rely on the short-term reactions of the re-

spective rival company. Rivals are assumed to experience positive information signaling

effects if they have large (more than 5%) or very large (more than 10%) abnormal gains

around the transaction announcement, in the following simply referred to as ‘gaining

rivals’ and ‘heavily gaining rivals’, respectively. Rivals are assumed to experience

negative competitive effects if they have large (less than -5%) or very large (less than -

10%) abnormal losses around the transaction announcement, in the following simply

referred to as ‘losing rivals’ and ‘heavily losing rivals’, respectively.

In addition, I choose to select the rival events not only by using an absolute per-

centage cut-off, but by also including a relative standard-deviation based requirement.

That is, a short-term absolute rival cumulative abnormal return (CAR) of 5% (10%) is

deemed to be a large (very large) return event if it is at least two standard deviations

from zero. I include this additional requirement, as a constant absolute return may be

important or not depending on the volatility of the rival’s stock returns. By combining

an absolute cut-off with the requirement for a two standard deviation move, I make sure

that the sample is not dominated by high volatility stocks and that, at the same time, a

minimum absolute price change is needed for low volatility stocks to qualify for an

event, ensuring a general ‘relevance’ of the rival return events.12

10 The mean (median) correlation of the 30 rivals is 0.257 (0.222). However, as the minimum correla-tion is only 0.008, I require a minimum correlation of 0.15. This removes about 13% of potential ri-vals. This screen ensures that I do not spuriously include lowly correlated rivals in the analysis.

11 I end the correlation estimation the month before the transaction so as to not run the risk of any bias due to market rumours in the run-up to the acquisition. I can report that the results are robust both to the length of the correlation estimation window (250, 180, or 120 days) and the gap before the trans-action (none, one month, two months).

12 To my knowledge I am the first to use such a combination. So far, the literature has focused on either absolute cut-offs (Brown, Harlow and Tinic (1988), Bremer and Sweeney (1991), Cox and Peterson (1994), Park (1995)) or relative cut-offs (Pritamani and Singal (2001)). However, I can report that my results remain quantitatively and qualitatively similar, if I use absolute cut-offs of 5% and 10% only.

Page 33: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

18

For the short-term event study, I base the methodology on Brown and Warner

(1985) and use the modified market model to estimate abnormal returns. I do not use the

market model because, for many rivals, there are months with several merger an-

nouncements, which implies a high probability of other bid announcements occurring in

the estimation period. Any abnormal returns caused by these announcements may bias

the estimation.13 I calculate the CAR for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the an-

nouncement date as:14

2

2,,]2,2[ )(

ttmti RRCAR , (2.1)

where Ri,t is rival i’s return on date t and Rm,t is the return for the equal-weighted CRSP

index on date t.

For each sample year, Table 2.1 shows the number of deals, the percentage of

the total number of deals during that specific year, as well as the average reaction of

equal-weighted portfolios of rivals to the M&A announcements. The table reveals that

most of the transactions take place at the height of the economy-wide merger wave at

the end of the 1990s. On average, positive information-signaling outweighs the negative

competitive effects of M&A, resulting in positive and significant rival reactions of

0.056%.15

13 Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) do not use the market model for the same reasons. Brown and Warner (1980) show that weighting the market return by a firm’s beta does not significantly improve the estimation.

14 My main findings are not susceptible to the choice of the event window length. They also hold for a shorter time horizon, such as three days, to estimate CARs.

15 This finding is consistent with the findings of Song and Walkling (2000), Fee and Thomas (2004), and Shahrur (2005) who document that the positive information-signaling effects of M&A an-nouncements, on average, outweigh the competitive effects of the deals.

Page 34: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

19

Table 2.1: Annual Distribution of M&A Transactions and Average Rival Reactions The sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. For each year, the table shows the number of deals, the per-centage of the total number of deals during that specific year, as well as the average rival reaction to M&A announcements during that year. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the equal-weighted rival portfolio for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. t-statistics for the total sample are provided in brack-ets.

Year Number As % of Average Rival of Deals All Deals CAR in %

1985 93 3.70 0.338 1986 90 3.58 0.304 1987 85 3.39 -0.323 1988 74 2.95 -0.146 1989 58 2.31 0.426 1990 31 1.23 -0.054 1991 41 1.63 -0.059 1992 52 2.07 -0.699 1993 73 2.91 -0.456 1994 106 4.22 0.195 1995 149 5.93 0.086 1996 167 6.65 0.211 1997 259 10.31 0.183 1998 259 10.31 0.178 1999 260 10.35 -0.098 2000 199 7.93 0.231 2001 131 5.22 -0.345 2002 70 2.79 -0.762 2003 101 4.02 0.078 2004 111 4.42 0.412 2005 102 4.06 0.332

Total 2,511 100.00 0.056 (2.02)

Figure 2.1 shows the historical probability distribution of the 30 most-correlated rival’s

CARs. As expected, most reactions are centered around zero, with 71.2% of rivals ex-

periencing CARs between -5% and +5%. What is more interesting, 14.7% of rivals ex-

perience CARs of more than 5%, a clear sign of positive information signaling of the

M&A announcement, and 14.1% of rivals experience CARs of less than -5%, indicative

of the negative competitive effects of the transaction. In the following, I will concen-

trate on these extremes of the CAR distribution to examine the long-term effects of

M&A transactions on rivals who are clearly affected by the announcement.

Page 35: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

20

Figure 2.1: Historical Distribution of Rival Cumulative Abnormal Returns The sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. The figure shows a histogram of rival short-term reactions to the deal announcement. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correla-tion to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark.

Historical Distribution of Rival Cumulative Abnormal Returns

0,6% 0,9% 1,0% 1,4% 1,8%2,3%

3,1%

4,1%

5,7%

7,6%

9,2%10,1% 9,7%

8,5%

6,9%

5,4%

4,1%3,1%

2,3% 1,9%1,5% 1,1% 0,9% 0,7%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

-12% to

-11%

-11%to

-10%

-10% to

-9%

-9%to

-8%

-8%to

-7%

-7% to -6

%

-6%to

-5%

-5% to -4

%

-4%to

-3%

-3%to

-2%

-2% to -1

%

-1%to

0%

0% to 1%

1%to

2%

2%to 3%

3% to 4%

4%to

5%

5% to 6%

6%to

7%

7% to

8%

8% to 9%

9% to 10

%

10%to

11%

11% to

12%

CAR Range

Prob

abili

ty

Historical Distribution of Rival Cumulative Abnormal Returns

0,6% 0,9% 1,0% 1,4% 1,8%2,3%

3,1%

4,1%

5,7%

7,6%

9,2%10,1% 9,7%

8,5%

6,9%

5,4%

4,1%3,1%

2,3% 1,9%1,5% 1,1% 0,9% 0,7%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

-12% to

-11%

-11%to

-10%

-10% to

-9%

-9%to

-8%

-8%to

-7%

-7% to -6

%

-6%to

-5%

-5% to -4

%

-4%to

-3%

-3%to

-2%

-2% to -1

%

-1%to

0%

0% to 1%

1%to

2%

2%to 3%

3% to 4%

4%to

5%

5% to 6%

6%to

7%

7% to

8%

8% to 9%

9% to 10

%

10%to

11%

11% to

12%

CAR Range

Prob

abili

ty

Table 2.2 shows the number of rivals experiencing large and very large return events in

each sample year as well as the respective average CAR. Overall, there are 5,408 large

and 2,079 very large loss events, while there are 6,138 large and 2,401 very large gain

events. The table also shows the size of the events: on average, rivals experience abso-

lute returns of roughly 10.6% (16%) for the case of large (very large) return events. The

CAR pattern is fairly consistent over time, with a maximum in the high volatility period

of 2000.

Page 36: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

21

Table 2.2: Annual Distribution of Rivals with Large Short-Term Reactions The sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. For each year, the table shows the number of rivals with large (very large) short-term gains and losses. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. Large (very large) gains and losses are defined as (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% (10%), respec-tively, given (2) at least a 2 standard deviation distance from zero. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnormal returns is estimated over the same 250-day window as the correlations.

Year Number of Rival Events Average Rival CAR in % Very

Large Losses

Large Losses

Large Gains

VeryLarge Gains

Very Large

Losses

Large Losses

Large Gains

VeryLarge Gains

1985 22 122 178 36 -13.501 -8.030 8.262 13.792 1986 25 123 174 43 -14.744 -8.591 8.857 14.898 1987 65 226 228 52 -16.110 -9.694 8.674 14.116 1988 29 141 123 34 -13.100 -8.167 9.203 14.977 1989 5 65 113 20 -12.421 -7.260 8.367 14.464 1990 21 81 83 27 -16.223 -9.282 9.396 15.125 1991 35 110 110 42 -13.965 -9.208 10.194 14.999 1992 37 131 72 27 -13.272 -8.794 10.199 15.580 1993 35 116 95 37 -13.375 -9.022 9.934 14.372 1994 33 168 202 70 -14.600 -8.505 9.408 13.224 1995 62 226 269 86 -14.127 -8.938 9.555 15.135 1996 89 244 326 144 -17.080 -10.784 10.661 15.027 1997 178 507 695 228 -16.607 -10.487 9.630 14.932 1998 320 757 838 361 -14.921 -10.444 10.961 15.867 1999 283 739 695 345 -15.796 -10.556 12.165 17.197 2000 360 599 742 425 -18.604 -14.145 13.673 18.249 2001 232 374 344 171 -17.520 -13.581 12.445 17.548 2002 100 205 197 71 -16.810 -11.976 10.123 15.140 2003 50 160 190 67 -13.616 -9.230 9.551 14.228 2004 48 151 230 65 -13.771 -9.003 8.745 13.361 2005 50 163 234 50 -13.406 -8.877 8.416 13.556

Total 2,079 5,408 6,138 2,401 -16.103 -10.578 10.613 16.013

2.3.3 Long-Term Performance

For the evaluation of long-term performance, appropriate adjustment for risk becomes

critical. First, even small errors in risk adjustment can make an economically large dif-

ference when calculating abnormal returns over longer horizons spanning months or

years, while such errors make little difference for short-term event windows. Second,

the question of the correct model for expected returns is unresolved in the asset pricing

literature, and therefore long-horizon abnormal return estimates suffer from the bad

Page 37: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

22

model problem (Kothari and Warner (2007)). Essentially, as emphasized by Fama

(1970, 1998), any test of long-horizon abnormal returns is a joint test of market effi-

ciency and the model of expected returns employed. Bearing this caveat in mind, I care-

fully proceed in selecting the best available empirical methods for the evaluation of ri-

val long-term performance.

Generally, there are two main methods used for measuring long-term stock price

performance: buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) and the calendar-time portfolio

approach. Despite of an extensive literature, there is no clear winner in a comparison of

the two.16 Therefore, I use both in the empirical investigations. In general, BHARs more

accurately represent an investors’ actual investment experience than the periodic

(monthly) rebalancing entailed in the calendar-time portfolio approach (Lyon, Barber

and Tsai (1999)). Furthermore, Loughran and Ritter (2000) show that the BHAR meth-

odology has substantially higher statistical power to detect abnormal performance than

the calendar-time method.17 The BHAR approach is also known as the characteristic-

based matching approach as it involves matching event firms to non-event firms based

on stock characteristics such as size and book-to-market. I use a matching firm approach

to avoid the skewness problems associated with the use of matching reference portfolios

(Barber and Lyon (1997)). Specifically, for each of the event firms, I first identify all

firms with a market capitalization between 70% and 130% of the market capitalization

of the event firm. Among these firms, I then choose the firm with the book-to-market

ratio closest to that of the event firm. Once a control firm j is identified, a T-month

BHAR for event firm i can be calculated by:

T

ttj

T

ttiTti RRBHAR

1,

1,],[, )1()1( , (2.2)

16 A selected list of this literature includes Barber and Lyon (1997), Kothari and Warner (1997), Fama (1998), Lyon, Barber and Tsai (1999), Mitchell and Stafford (2000) and Kothari and Warner (2007).

17 The use of the BHAR methodology is substantiated by the fact that its statistical problems only be-come severe at very long post-event horizons such as three to five years. Therefore, as I focus on shorter horizons up to a year after the event, I encounter less severe statistical problems than other long-term performance studies.

Page 38: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

23

If a matching firm is delisted from CRSP, the next firm with the closest book-to-market

ratio is chosen as additional matching firm. Following Loughran and Vijh (1997), re-

turns for the additional matching firms are spliced in from that point in time going for-

ward. For the 12-month post-event horizon, only 9% of the rival sample needs a second

matching firm and only 1% a third. Finally, for the sample of event firms, the mean

BHAR is calculated as the simple average of the individual firm BHARs. Statistical

significance can be evaluated using a standard cross-sectional t-statistic as the use of a

single control firm alleviates the skewness bias (Barber and Lyon (1997)).

However, the issue of cross-sectional correlation remains and cannot be ne-

glected as the majority of transactions and, therefore, the majority of rival events cluster

in the five years from 1996 to 2000 (see Table 2.1 and Table 2.2). Furthermore, cross-

sectional correlation may be due to two additional sources: over-representation of some

industries with high merger activity in the sample and overlapping long-horizon returns

for multiple-event firms. In principle, these issues can be accommodated in a BHAR

approach using the methodology developed by Jegadeesh and Karceski (2004). How-

ever, I choose to use a calendar-time portfolio approach instead to evaluate the robust-

ness of the results with an alternative methodology.

The calendar-time methodology was initially developed by Jaffe (1974) and

Mandelker (1974) and is especially advocated by Fama (1998) and Mitchell and Staf-

ford (2000). The approach involves calculating calendar-time portfolios for firms ex-

periencing an event. Suppose I want to evaluate long-term performance over T=12

months. Then, in each calendar month over the entire sample period, a portfolio is con-

structed comprising all firms with an event within the previous 12 months. As the num-

ber of firms in a portfolio is not constant over time, the portfolio is rebalanced every

month and the equal-weighted return is calculated for every sample month. The result-

ing time-series of returns is free of any cross-correlation issues and can therefore be

used for standard statistical tests.

I report average monthly raw returns as well as average monthly abnormal re-

turns using the size and book-to-market matched control firm from the BHAR approach.

However, more interestingly, the calendar-time portfolio approach is usually employed

Page 39: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

24

with a different risk-adjustment methodology by estimating abnormal returns using a

multi-factor asset pricing model in the spirit of the intertemportal capital asset pricing

model of Merton (1973) and the arbitrage pricing theory of Ross (1976). Therefore, the

time-series of calendar-time portfolio excess returns is regressed on a three-factor model

comprising the three Fama and French (1993) market, size, and book-to-market factors.

Specifically, I regress:

tptptptftmpptftp HMLhSMBsRRbaRR ,,,,, )()()( (2.3)

where Rp,t is the portfolio return comprising t months of event firms, for t=(1,3,6,9,12),

Rf,t is the risk-free rate, Rm,t is the value-weighted CRSP index, bp, sp, and hp are the co-

efficients of the Fama and French (1993) market (Rm-Rf), size (SMB), and book-to-

market (HML) portfolio returns.18 Inferences about the abnormal performance can be

drawn on the basis of the estimated intercept ap and its statistical significance. To ac-

count for heteroskedasticity due to the changing number of portfolio firms and possible

autocorrelation, I use Newey and West (1987) heteroskedasticity- and autocorrelation-

corrected standard errors with three monthly lags to calculate t-statistics.19

2.4 Results2.4.1 Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Returns

Based on the events identified by the short-term event study, I proceed in evaluating the

long-term performance of rival companies. Table 2.3 displays the main findings using

the BHAR methodology with size and book-to-market matched control firms. For the

large return events in Panel A, I find positive long-horizon post-event BHARs for gain-

ing rivals and negative long-horizon post-event BHARs for losing rivals. Rivals who

18 SMB (small minus big) is the difference between the return on the portfolio of “small” and “big” stocks and HML (high minus low) is the difference between the return on the portfolio of “high” and “low” book-to-market stocks. The construction of these portfolio returns is discussed in detail in Fama and French (1993). I thank Kenneth French for providing the factor data on his website.

19 I chose the number of monthly lags using the time-series-dependent rule of thumb 0.5T1/3. However, the results are similar for any other reasonable number of lags. In addition, a simple White (1980) correction for heteroskedasticity shows similar results.

Page 40: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

25

have large gains due to positive information-signaling at the announcement of a deal

experience continued positive long-term returns amounting to a significant average

BHAR of 2.844% after 12 months. Rivals who suffer large losses due to the negative

competitive effects of a M&A transaction experience continued negative long-term re-

turns resulting in a highly significant negative average BHAR of 8.146% after 12

months. Testing the two samples for differences shows an average BHAR difference of

10.990% with a t-statistic of over six.

Table 2.3: Long-Term Rival Buy-and-Hold-Abnormal ReturnsThe sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. The table shows the long-term buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) of rivals with large (Panel A) and very large (Panel B) short-term returns around the deal an-nouncement. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. Large (very large) re-turn events are defined as (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% (10%), respectively, given (2) at least a 2 standard deviation distance from zero. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modi-fied market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnor-mal returns is estimated over the same 250-day window as the correlations. Long-term performance is evaluated using buy-and-hold abnormal returns with size and book-to-market matched control firms as benchmark. Returns are in percent, t-statistics are shown in parentheses.

Holding Period 1 3 6 9 12

Panel A: Large Return Events

BHAR in % 0.383 0.207 0.431 1.101 2.844 (t-statistic) (1.51) (0.47) (0.65) (1.19) (2.27) Gaining

Rivals (1) N 6,111 6,048 5,934 5,818 5,708

BHAR in % -0.164 -0.225 -2.494 -4.532 -8.146 (t-statistic) (-0.60) (-0.43) (-2.96) (-4.31) (-6.29) Losing

Rivals (2) N 5,386 5,349 5,276 5,193 5,096

BHAR in % 0.547 0.432 2.925 5.633 10.990 Difference (1)-(2) (t-statistic) (1.47) (0.64) (2.76) (4.03) (6.09)

Panel B: Very Large Return Events

BHAR in % 0.354 -0.057 0.767 1.259 4.614 (t-statistic) (0.71) (-0.07) (0.59) (0.69) (1.87)

HeavilyGaining

Rivals (1) N 2,388 2,353 2,301 2,249 2,198

BHAR in % -0.369 -0.512 -2.689 -5.486 -12.895 (t-statistic) (-0.69) (-0.48) (-1.78) (-2.55) (-4.80)

HeavilyLosing

Rivals (2) N 2,069 2,052 2,024 1,992 1,946

BHAR in % 0.722 0.455 3.455 6.745 17.509 Difference (1)-(2) (t-statistic) (0.99) (0.34) (1.74) (2.41) (4.81)

Page 41: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

26

Turning to the very large return events in Panel B, we can observe that the results are

stronger if we examine a more extreme event definition. Over a holding period of 12

months, heavily gaining rivals experience a significantly positive average post-event

BHAR of 4.614%, while heavily losing rivals experience a significantly negative aver-

age BHAR of 12.895%. The average BHAR difference of 17.509% is highly statisti-

cally significant with a t-statistic of almost five.

Figure 2.2 visualizes the results for large rival return events in an event-time

graph displaying average BHARs. The upper solid line shows the results for gaining

rivals, the lower solid line for losing rivals; 95% confidence intervals are indicated by

the dotted lines.

Figure 2.2: Event-Time Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Rival ReturnsThe sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. The figure shows event-time buy-and-hold-abnormal returns of rivals with large short-term gains (upper solid line) or losses (lower solid line) around the deal an-nouncement (month 0). Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correla-tion to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. Large gains and losses are defined as (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% given (2) at least a 2 standard deviation distance from zero. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnormal returns is esti-mated over the same 250-day window as the correlations. Long-term performance is evaluated using buy-and-hold abnormal returns with size/book-to-market matched control firms as benchmark. Returns are in percent, 95% confidence intervals are indicated by the dotted lines.

Event-Time Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Rival Returns

-20-16-12

-8-4048

121620

-1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Event Month

BH

AR

in %

Event-Time Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Rival Returns

-20-16-12

-8-4048

121620

-1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Event Month

BH

AR

in %

Page 42: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

27

After zero returns in pre-event month t-1, rival firms experience per definitionem large

gains or large losses in the transaction month t. This event is followed by a continuous

drift of returns in the same direction as the initial reaction to the deal announcement. For

positive events, the drift is only marginal in the first six post-event months as already

indicated in Table 2.2, but afterward picks up pace and becomes highly significant after

12 months. For negative events, the line is consistently downward sloping with statisti-

cally significant negative post-event performance already reached after six months. I

also evaluated longer time-horizons of two and three years after the event, but I was not

able to find any reliable additional drift beyond the first post-event year.20

Overall, from these results we can conclude that rivals of M&A target firms who

show a large reaction to the deal announcement experience a continued return drift in

the same direction as the initial reaction. This indicates that capital markets underreact

to the information contained in M&A transactions for the stock price performance of

rivals, a result which fits well in the literature on underreaction of capital markets to

new information (Frazzini (2006), Jackson and Johnson (2006), Zhang (2006)). Also

consistent with the literature, the return drift after negative events is considerably larger

and more consistently statistically significant, implying that “bad news travels slowly”

and is only incorporated with a considerable time-lag into stock prices, possibly due to

market frictions such as short-sale constraints (Hong, Lim and Stein (2000), Chan

(2003)).

2.4.2 Calendar-Time Portfolios

In order to investigate the robustness of the main findings, I employ calendar-time port-

folio returns as an alternative methodology to the use of BHARs. Table 2.4 shows the

results when I use the calendar-time methodology based on raw returns and size and

book-to-market adjusted returns. For the 12-month holding period, Panel A shows that

the average monthly raw return for the gaining rivals portfolio of 1.423% is substan-

tially larger than the average return of 0.794% for the losing rivals portfolio, resulting in

20 The peak of the post-event BHAR appears after about 15 months; afterwards, I cannot find any fur-ther abnormal performance. Results are available on request from the author.

Page 43: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

28

a highly significant average monthly raw return of 0.629% (annualized 7.55%) for the

long-short portfolio.

Table 2.4: Calendar-Time Portfolio ReturnsThe sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. The table shows average monthly calendar-time portfolio raw returns (Panel A) and adjusted returns (Panel B) for rivals with large short-term returns around the deal announcement. Adjusted returns are calculated with size and book-to-market matched control firms as benchmark. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. Gaining and losing rivals are defined as rivals with (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% given (2) at least a 2 standard devia-tion distance from zero. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnormal returns is estimated over the same 250-day window as the correlations. Returns are in monthly percent, t-statistics are shown in parentheses.

Holding Period

1 3 6 9 12

Panel A: Raw Returns

1.861 1.772 1.522 1.482 1.423 GainingRivals (1) (3.61) (4.16) (3.70) (3.65) (3.54)

0.701 0.810 0.742 0.846 0.794 LosingRivals (2) (1.36) (1.70) (1.57) (1.78) (1.71)

1.194 0.963 0.780 0.636 0.629 Long-Short (1)-(2) (2.83) (3.65) (4.04) (3.52) (4.03)

Panel B: Size-BM Adjusted Returns

1.105 0.598 0.414 0.326 0.257 GainingRivals (1) (2.62) (2.52) (2.54) (2.32) (2.09)

-0.448 -0.103 -0.336 -0.261 -0.381 LosingRivals (2) (-1.27) (-0.47) (-1.86) (-1.52) (-2.55)

1.584 0.701 0.751 0.587 0.638 Long-Short (1)-(2) (2.89) (2.37) (3.63) (3.41) (4.46)

This result carries over into Panel B where I consider the same risk-adjustment as in the

BHAR methodology: returns adjusted by size and book-to-market matched control

firms. With the use of a benchmark, we can now also directly interpret the statistical

significance of the individual portfolios. For the 12-month holding period, average

monthly size and book-to-market adjusted returns are a significantly positive 0.257%

for the portfolio of gaining rivals and a significantly negative 0.381% for the portfolio

of losing rivals. This translates into a highly statistically significant adjusted return of

Page 44: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

29

0.638% (annualized 7.68%) for the long-short portfolio, a finding comparable to the raw

return results of Panel A.

Overall, calendar-time portfolio returns appear generally larger at the shorter ho-

rizon: scaled up to the respective holding periods, the adjusted returns for the long-short

portfolio of 1.584% after one month, 2.103% after three months and 4.504% after six

months are larger than the BHAR differences reported in Panel A of Table 2.3 (0.547%,

0.432%, and 2.925%, respectively). However, for the nine and 12-month holding peri-

ods the claendar-time adjusted returns of 5.282% and 7.655%, respectively, are compa-

rable with and smaller than the average BHARs of 5.633% and 10.990%, respectively.

These differences in average returns show the effects of event clustering in the sample.21

Overall, however, the claendar-time portfolio results indicate that my general findings

of underreaction by capital markets to the information contained in M&A announce-

ments for rival firms is robust to the issue of cross-sectional event correlation, as evi-

denced by the high significance of the long-short portfolio returns at all post-event hori-

zons.

In addition, calendar-time portfolios provide for another possibility: the use of

an alternative risk-adjustment methodology based on calendar-time multi-factor regres-

sions. Table 2.5 shows the results using the three-factor model described in Section

2.3.3. In addition to the regression intercepts, Table 2.5 also reports the factor loadings

of the portfolios. Examining the results, it is evident that both the portfolios of rivals

with large gains and large losses represent stocks with high risk with respect to the

Fama-French three-factor model: both portfolios have market betas above one and sig-

nificantly positive loadings on the size-factor (with negligible exposure to the value

factor). Combining the two portfolios, the long-short portfolio of rivals shows balanced

risk exposure: it has a significantly negative exposure to the market factor and no expo-

sure to the size and value factors.

21 These results imply that during the time period of the majority of the events (1996 to 2000) the return drift was less pronounced for the shorter holding periods and more pronounced for the 12-month ho-rizon, a deduction which I confirmed in unreported subsamples.

Page 45: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

30

Table 2.5: Calendar-Time Portfolio Three-Factor AlphasThis table shows three-factor alphas, coefficients, t-statistics, and R² values from a monthly time-series regression of , where the left-hand side variable is the monthly excess return for a portfolio of rivals with large return events in the last t months and the right-hand side variables are contemporaneous Fama and French (1993) market, size, and book-to-market factor mimicking portfolio returns. Panel A reports the results for gaining rivals, Panel B presents the findings for losing rivals, and Panel C displays the results for a long-short portfolio. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. Gaining and losing rivals are defined as rivals with (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% given (2) at least a 2 standard deviation distance from zero. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnormal returns is estimated over the same 250-day win-dow as the correlations. Alphas are in monthly percent, t-statistics based on Newey and West (1987) autocorrelation- and heteroskedasticity robust standard errors with three lags are shown in parentheses below the coefficient estimates.

Holding Period Pa (%) Pb (Rm-Rf) Ps (SMB) Ph (HML) R² (%)

Panel A: Gaining Rivals 1 0.849 1.107 0.628 -0.220 64.39 (2.59) (17.25) (6.52) (-1.75) 3 0.619 1.125 0.599 -0.032 78.86 (3.01) (24.42) (8.03) (-0.32) 6 0.273 1.213 0.598 0.077 89.48 (1.79) (36.18) (11.80) (1.15) 9 0.248 1.202 0.585 0.059 90.82 (2.04) (38.91) (11.51) (0.95) 12 0.173 1.225 0.538 0.073 92.12 (1.57) (40.66) (8.42) (1.32) Panel B: Losing Rivals 1 -0.456 1.273 0.382 -0.159 63.80 (-1.53) (13.63) (2.25) (-1.07) 3 -0.455 1.327 0.449 -0.056 77.59 (-1.99) (18.34) (3.41) (-0.45) 6 -0.599 1.397 0.485 0.026 83.80 (-2.87) (19.52) (3.70) (0.21) 9 -0.482 1.383 0.474 0.013 81.95 (-2.10) (19.24) (3.51) (0.11) 12 -0.554 1.378 0.494 0.075 82.82 (-2.62) (20.12) (3.73) (0.63) Panel C: Long-Short 1 1.297 -0.157 0.239 -0.075 2.60 (3.49) (-1.53) (1.13) (-0.41) 3 1.073 -0.202 0.150 0.025 5.63 (3.71) (-2.58) (1.18) (0.16) 6 0.873 -0.183 0.113 0.051 8.94 (4.03) (-2.97) (1.08) (0.37) 9 0.729 -0.182 0.111 0.046 9.84 (3.75) (-3.18) (1.13) (0.40) 12 0.726 -0.154 0.044 -0.002 7.62 (4.60) (-3.00) (0.57) (-0.03)

tPtPtPtftmPPtftP HMLhSMBsRRbaRR ,,,,, )()()(

Page 46: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

31

Overall, we can conclude that the results are robust to the particular risk-adjustment

methodology chosen. My findings consistently indicate that capital markets do not im-

mediately incorporate the positive information signaling and negative competitive ef-

fects of M&A announcement into rival stock prices, resulting in a return drift of up to a

year after the event.

2.4.3 Size Groups

I show that both gaining and losing rivals experience a return drift into the same direc-

tion as the initial reaction for up to 12 months after the announcement. This raises the

question of whether this return drift is exploitable by the general investor. Therefore, I

investigate whether the results hold across size-based subsamples of stocks or whether

the findings are only relevant for small, illiquid stocks. I follow Fama and French

(2007) in differentiating between three size groups: micro-cap, small, and big firms. The

breakpoints are the 20th and 50th market capitalization percentiles of NYSE stocks in the

month before the M&A announcement.22 These three size groups are roughly in line

with the definition used by many investment managers. To put the breakpoints into per-

spective, in November 2005 (the last pre-event month) the breakpoint between micro-

cap and small firms is $627 million, and the breakpoint between small and big firms is

$1,954 million.23

The long-term returns for the different size based subsamples of rivals are shown

in Table 2.6. For micro-cap (Panel A), small (Panel B) and large rivals (Panel C), the

12-month BHAR after large losses is -7.136%, -10.086% and -7.345%, respectively.

Thus, losing rivals experience a negative post-announcement drift irrespective of their

22 However, as opposed to Fama and French (2007), I exclude the tiniest micro-caps from the analysis by requiring all event firms to have a stock price of at least 5$ and to be larger than the 5th market capitalization percentile of NYSE stocks in the month before the M&A announcement. To put the latter cutoff into perspective, the 5th percentile in November 2005 (the last pre-event month) is $176 million.

23 In addition, Fama and French (2007) report that their group of big firms is sometimes split again into mega-caps and mid-caps by investment managers. I checked for the robustness of my results across the group of big firms by splitting it again at the 80th market capitalization percentile of NYSE stocks. However, I can report that the results for mid-caps and mega-caps are qualitatively and quan-titatively similar.

Page 47: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

32

size. As size is a proxy for short-sale constraints, this result implies that market frictions

are not a key driver of the negative post-event drift.

Table 2.6: Long-Term Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Returns for Rival Size GroupsThe sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2005 with a transaction value of at least $100 million, publicly listed target and acquirer firms, and the intent of the acquirer to purchase at least 50% of shares. The table shows the long-term buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) of microcap (Panel A), small (Panel B) and big (Panel C) rivals with large short-term returns around the deal announcement. The breakpoints for the size groups are the 20th and 50th market capitaliza-tion percentiles of NYSE stocks in the month before the transaction. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the highest return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transaction. Gaining and losing rivals are defined as rivals with (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% given (2) at least a 2 standard deviation distance from zero. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Ab-normal returns are calculated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnormal returns is estimated over the same 250-day window as the correlations. Long-term performance is evaluated using buy-and-hold abnormal returns with size and book-to-market matched control firms as benchmark. Returns are in percent, t-statistics are shown in parentheses.

Holding Period

1 3 6 9 12

Panel A: Microcap RivalsBHAR in % -0.549 -0.818 -3.023 2.164 8.548 (t-statistic) (-0.75) (-0.61) (-1.60) (0.74) (2.04)

GainingRivals (1)

N 997 987 958 929 904 BHAR in % 0.859 0.858 -0.584 -2.565 -7.136 (t-statistic) (1.16) (0.57) (-0.18) (-0.75) (-1.46)

LosingRivals (2)

N 928 914 902 885 861 BHAR in % -1.408 -1.676 -2.438 4.729 15.684 Difference

(1)-(2) (t-statistic) (-1.35) (-0.83) (-0.66) (1.06) (2.45)

Panel B: Small RivalsBHAR in % 0.605 1.052 2.444 2.272 3.051 (t-statistic) (1.22) (1.23) (1.89) (1.22) (1.23)

GainingRivals (1)

N 1,875 1,846 1,813 1,776 1,733 BHAR in % -0.066 0.864 -3.200 -5.861 -10.086 (t-statistic) (-0.12) (0.81) (-2.32) (-2.83) (-4.46)

LosingRivals (2)

N 1,659 1,646 1,624 1,590 1,554 BHAR in % 0.671 0.188 5.644 8.133 13.137 Difference

(1)-(2) (t-statistic) (0.92) (0.14) (2.99) (2.93) (3.87)

Panel C: Big Rivals BHAR in % 0.540 0.036 0.324 0.116 1.049 (t-statistic) (1.75) (0.07) (0.40) (0.11) (0.75)

GainingRivals (1)

N 3,239 3,215 3,163 3,113 3,071 BHAR in % -0.562 -1.223 -2.704 -4.395 -7.345 (t-statistic) (-1.66) (-2.05) (-2.94) (-3.78) (-5.35)

LosingRivals (2)

N 2,799 2,789 2,750 2,718 2,681 BHAR in % 1.103 1.259 3.027 4.511 8.394 Difference

(1)-(2) (t-statistic) (2.41) (1.57) (2.47) (2.88) (4.27)

Page 48: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

33

A different picture evolves for gaining rivals. For micro-cap rivals in Panel A, the aver-

age 12-month BHAR is a significantly positive 8.548%. This return drift is substantially

larger than in the overall sample. It concurs with the intuition that positive information

signaling is more important for the smallest rivals: they face a higher takeover likeli-

hood and, therefore, experience a larger post-event drift. On the contrary, small rival

companies (Panel B) experience a positive but insignificant post-event drift of 3.051%.

For the big rival size-group, the 12-month average BHAR of 1.049% is even smaller

and without any statistical significance. Hence, we can conclude that the positive post-

event drift for gaining rivals is only relevant for micro-cap stocks.

2.4.4 Cross-Sectional Regressions

Finally, I employ cross-sectional regressions to investigate possible predictors of the

return drift. More specifically, I regress rival 12-month BHARs on a host of explanatory

variables related to the underlying causes of the rival events: the positive information-

signaling and negative competitive effects of M&A announcements. Any variables pre-

dicting takeover probabilities may be able to predict the long-term positive returns to

rivals following positive information-signaling events, while any variables determining

the negative competitive effects of M&A transactions may be able to predict the long-

term negative returns to rivals following announcements accompanied by negative com-

petitive effects.

To investigate the influence of the focus of the firm I employ a dummy equal to

one if the rival only has one business segment contributing more than 10% of sales ac-

cording to the Compustat segment files. More focused firms face a higher future take-

over probability given that they are more easily integrated into an acquirers existing

business lines without the need to finance, restructure, and eventually spin off unwanted

business segments in a conglomerate takeover. Therefore, I expect a positive sign for

this dummy in the cross-sectional BHAR regressions of gaining rivals, while the seg-

ment dummy should not have any significant influence in the BHAR regressions of los-

ing rivals. Also, I employ a number of independent variables that have been used in the

prior literature to explain the probability of takeovers and the competitive effects of

Page 49: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

34

M&A (see, e.g., Hasbrouck (1985), Ambrose and Megginson (1992), Akhigbe and Mar-

tin (2000) or Cremers, Nair and John (2007)). These variables include the rival’s size

(the natural logarithm of the market capitalization), valuation as measured by Tobin’s

Q, asset structure (property, plant, and equipment (PPE)), cash holdings, financial lev-

erage, and profitability. Table 2.7 presents the results of the cross-sectional regressions.

Table 2.7: Cross-Sectional Buy-and-Hold Abnormal Return Regressions This table shows the results of cross-sectional regressions of 12-month rival buy-and-hold abnormal re-turns (BHAR) on a host of explanatory variables. Panel A shows the results for large gain events, Panel B displays the finding for large loss events. Rivals are the 30 firms from the target’s industry with the high-est return correlation to the target measured over a 250-day window ending the month before the transac-tion. Gaining and losing rivals are defined as rivals with (1) a positive or negative CAR of 5% given (2) at least a 2 standard deviation distance from zero. The event CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the rival firm for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Abnormal returns are calcu-lated using the modified market model with the equal-weighted CRSP index as benchmark. The standard deviation of abnormal returns is estimated over the same 250-day window as the correlations. The seg-ment dummy in the regression is equal to one for firms with only one business segment and ln(market cap) is the natural logarithm of market capitalization. Tobin’s Q is calculated as market value of assets over book value of assets, where the market value of assets is estimated by the book value of assets plus market value of equity minus book value of equity. PPE is the ratio of net property, plant and equipment to total assets, cash is the ratio of cash and short-term investments to total assets, leverage is the ratio of book debt to total assets, and profitability is income before extraordinary items plus deferred taxes over total assets. All Compustat variables are industry-adjusted by subtracting the respective industry mean using Fama and French (1997) 48 industries. The regressions are estimated using a (I) pooled time-series cross-sectional regression approach and a (II) Fama and MacBeth (1973) approach based on each annual cohort of events from 1985 to 2005. For the pooled regressions, the t-statistics in parentheses are calcu-lated using White (1980) heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. For the Fama-MacBeth-regressions, the t-statistics in parentheses are calculated using Newey and West (1987) autocorrelation-correction with 1 lag. All coefficients are reported x100, the number of observations for the Fama-MacBeth approach is the number of years in the time-series.

Panel A: Gaining Rivals Panel B: Losing Rivals Method (I) Pooled (II) Fama-

MacBeth (I) Pooled (II) Fama-

MacBethSegment Dummy 0.369 5.768 2.336 0.512

(0.10) (1.30) (0.81) (0.17) Ln(Market Cap) -1.118 -0.761 0.767 1.284

(-1.16) (-0.79) (0.84) (1.22) Tobin’s Q 1.211 2.106 -0.533 -1.158

(1.80) (2.52) (-1.73) (-1.39) PPE 1.589 7.427 -4.290 1.104 (0.32) (0.99) (-0.73) (0.14) Cash 12.391 7.072 -3.554 -5.830

(1.24) (0.69) (-0.45) (-0.53) Leverage 0.332 0.423 1.103 0.949

(0.73) (0.46) (2.15) (1.82) Profitability 40.847 -11.662 17.624 -3.452 (2.80) (-0.64) (1.51) (-0.38) R² (%) 0.59 6.99 0.29 7.53 Observations 4,763 21 4,335 21

Page 50: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

35

Following Purnanandam and Swaminathan (2004), I estimate the regressions using (I) a

pooled time-series cross-sectional approach and (II) a Fama and MacBeth (1973) re-

gression approach. For the Fama-MacBeth approach, I estimate annual cross-sectional

regressions using each annual sample of gaining and losing rivals from 1985 to 2005

and then report the time-series average of the resulting 21 slope coefficients.24

Panel A of Table 2.7 presents the results for the BHAR regressions of gaining

rivals. First, we observe a statistically significant positive coefficient on Tobin’s Q for

both regression specifications. This finding is counterintuitive as firms with a high

valuation face a lower takeover likelihood (Hasbrouck (1985) and Cremers, Nair and

John (2007)), but apparently do face a higher post-event BHAR in my sample. Second,

the coefficient on profitability is significantly positive in the pooled regression ap-

proach, indicating that more profitable firms face a higher takeover likelihood and,

therefore, a higher post-event BHAR.25 The other regression variables, the segment

dummy, size, cash, PPE and leverage, are not statistically significant in any regression

specification.26

Panel B of Table 2.7 displays the findings for the BHAR regression after large

loss events. First, we observe consistently negative coefficients on Q in both regression

specifications, with statistical significance in the pooled regression. This finding indi-

cates that highly valued rivals are more negatively impacted by the competitive effects

associated with the related M&A announcements, therefore suffering more negative

long-term returns. Second, leverage has a statistically significant positive coefficient in

both regression specifications. This does not concur with the notion that financial lever-

24 This approach accounts for the effects of cross-sectional correlation discussed in the prior section, as cross-sectional information is only used for the coefficient estimation but the tests of statistical sig-nificance solely rely on time-series information. All independent variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% level to reduce the influence of outliers on the regression results.

25 However, the coefficient is insignificant and even reverses sign in the Fama-MacBeth regression, indicating that cross-sectional correlation due to event clustering may be responsible for spuriously significant results in the pooled regression approach.

26 The negative coefficient of size is consistent with the size group results from Section 2.4.3. The lack of statistical significance indicates that the relationship may not be linear. If I use dummy variables to replicate the size groups used in Section 2.4.3, the dummy for micro-cap gaining rivals is signifi-cantly positive.

Page 51: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

36

age limits a firms ability to make investments to respond to competitive challenges

(Stulz (1990)), thereby resulting in more negative competitive effects of a related M&A

announcement (Akhigbe and Martin (2000)). All other variables, the segment dummy,

size, PPE, cash holdings, and profitability are not statistically significant in any regres-

sion specification.

Overall, the regressions are only modestly successful in explaining the long-term

performance of related rivals. Further research into the underlying causes of the large

rival return events, the positive information signaling and negative competitive effects

of M&A announcements, is warranted in order to better understand the underreaction of

capital markets and the ensuing return predictability.

2.5 Conclusion

In this essay, I investigate the long-term performance of rival companies related to the

target of an acquisition. Using a sample of 2,511 deals from 1985 to 2005, I document

an underreaction of capital markets to the information contained in M&A announce-

ments. Following 6,138 large rival gain events due to positive information signaling and

5,408 large rival loss events due to the negative competitive effects of the deal, I find a

return drift into the same direction as the initial reaction for up to 12 months after the

announcement. These findings are robust to the methodology I use to measure long-

term performance: 12-month BHARs using size and book-to-market matched control

firms show a highly significant return difference of 10.990% between the large gain and

large loss sample, while the calendar-time portfolio approach using the same return ad-

justment results in an average monthly long-short return of 0.638% (7.66% annualized).

Using a three-factor asset pricing model for risk adjustment in the calendar-time ap-

proach results in an average monthly three-factor alpha for the long-short portfolio of

0.726% at the 12-month horizon (8.71% annualized).

In subsample tests, I find that the return drift after positive rival return events is

most pronounced for micro-cap rivals: they experience a 12-month post-event BHAR of

8.548%, while small and big rivals experience substantially smaller and insignificant

Page 52: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

37

return drift. This finding is intuitive as the smallest rivals face a higher takeover likeli-

hood, resulting in a higher positive return drift after the initial reaction to the M&A an-

nouncement. However, I find that rival size is not important in determining the return

drift after negative return events. I use cross-sectional BHAR regressions in order to

better understand the drivers of the return drift, but the regressions do not paint a precise

picture of the long-term BHARs to rivals. Further research into the underlying causes of

the large rival return events, positive information signaling and negative competitive

effects of M&A, is warranted in order to better understand the underreaction of capital

markets and the ensuing return predictability.

Overall, my results indicate that capital markets do not immediately incorporate

the positive information signaling and negative competitive effects of M&A announce-

ments into rival stock prices, resulting in a return drift of up to a year after the event.

Page 53: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

38

Appendix

My accounting data are from the annual Compustat files. Book equity is defined as total

assets (data item 6), minus liabilities (181), plus balance sheet deferred taxes and in-

vestment tax credit (35) if available, minus preferred stock liquidating value (10) if

available, or redemption value (56) if available, or carrying value (130). Asset structure

is calculated as the ratio of net property, plant, and equipment (8) to total assets (6),

cash holdings as the ratio of cash and short-term investments (1) to total assets, financial

leverage as the ratio of long-term debt (9) plus debt in current liabilities (34) to total

assets, and profitability as the ratio of income before extraordinary items (18) plus in-

come statement deferred taxes (50) to total assets.

Following the usual practice in the asset pricing literature based on Fama and

French (1992), I match accounting variables for fiscal year-ends in year t 1 with CRSP

returns from July of year t to June of year t+1. The book-to-market ratio is book equity

divided by CRSP market capitalization (number of shares outstanding times share price)

at the end of December of year t 1. Tobin’s Q is the ratio of market assets to book as-

sets, where the market value of assets is total assets minus book equity plus market eq-

uity. As before, market equity is the CRSP market capitalization at the end of December

of year t 1.

Page 54: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

39

3 Predictability of Industry Returns After M&A

Announcements

Abstract

This essay documents a strong and prevalent drift in long-term industry returns after

M&A announcements. Specifically, industries that experience positive average an-

nouncement reactions continue to do well in the future, while industries that experience

negative average announcement reactions continue to do poorly. Industry M&A invest-

ment strategies, which buy positively reacting industries and sell negatively reacting

industries, appear profitable even after controlling for size and book-to-market effects

in returns. Profitability has strengthened over time and seems to exist also for the larg-

est stocks. The evidence suggests that capital markets underreact to the industry-wide

information provided by merger announcements.

I thank my co-authors Timo Gebken and Lutz Johanning, as well as Yakov Amihud, Hermann Lo-carek-Junge (discussant), Gaston Michel, Julie Ng, Andreas Rathgeber (discussant), Dirk Schiereck, Sebastian Werner and Felix Zeidler for valuable comments and insights. I am also grateful for the input of conference participants at the 13th German Finance Association (DGF) conference in Oestrich-Winkel, the WHU Campus For Finance conference in Vallendar, the HVB doctoral seminar in Eltville, and work-shop participants at European Business School. Any remaining errors are mine.

Page 55: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

40

3.1 Introduction

The financial literature has extensively examined the effects of M&A announcements

on the stock returns of bidding firms. Short-horizon event studies show that bidders lose

or, at most, break even when announcing a transaction. In addition, recent long-term

event studies measure significantly negative abnormal returns for the three to five years

following merger completion.27 Although the acquiring firm shareholders lose signifi-

cantly at the announcement of a transaction, studies that measure the intra-industry ef-

fects of M&A transactions show that rivals experience significantly positive abnormal

returns when the industry consolidates. Thus, positive information-signaling effects, on

average, outweigh negative competitive effects for rivals.28

In a recent study, Funke et al. (2008) show that these positive industry reactions

are not pervasive over time. At the beginning of an industry-wide consolidation process

intra-industry effects are significantly positive. However, due to increasing competition,

intra-industry effects decrease steadily and become negative at the end of such a con-

solidation process. Hence, time-varying competitive effects of M&A activity, depend-

ing on time-varying industry structure, are responsible for a significant difference in

intra-industry reactions over time. However, as industry structure and therefore the

competitive effects of M&A activity change relatively slowly over time, their evidence

suggests a certain persistence in average monthly intra-industry announcement reac-

tions.

As short horizon intra-industry effects directly impact industry returns, such a

persistence may also influence long-term industry performance. To the author’s best

knowledge, long-term industry returns after merger announcements have not yet been

27 A number of deal and firm characteristics impact bidding firms’ returns. Moeller, Schlingemann and Stulz (2004) show that only large bidders lose significantly around the transaction announcement. Loughran and Vijh (1997) document that cash bidders gain significantly in the months following a transaction announcement, although acquirers experience negative long-term returns on average.

28 Eckbo (1983) and Eckbo (1985) find positive intra-industry effects for the announcement of horizon-tal mergers. Song and Walkling (2000) document positive abnormal returns to rivals of the target for their sample of horizontal and non-horizontal deals. In more recent studies, Fee and Thomas (2004) and Shahrur (2005) also show that competitors experience positive stock market effects at the an-nouncement of horizontal deals.

Page 56: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

41

studied. Therefore, the objective of this essay is to investigate whether there are system-

atic differences in industry returns after M&A announcements depending on the initial

intra-industry effects of the deal.

Using a dataset of 16,483 transactions that occur within one of 20 industries be-

tween 1985 and 2002 I investigate whether the average industry reaction in previous

periods affects the intra-industry effects of transaction announcements in later periods. I

find that this is indeed the case: the cumulative abnormal return (CAR) at the an-

nouncement of an M&A transaction depends on the average reaction to merger an-

nouncements in the same industry in the previous month. Thus, my findings concur with

the intuition in Funke et al. (2008) that intra-industry effects are persistent over time.

This raises an interesting question as daily abnormal announcement returns directly im-

pact monthly industry returns for the respective month. Do monthly industry returns

differ conditional on the direction of the average announcement reaction in the previous

month?

Based on this result I look at monthly industry returns after merger announce-

ments. Paralleling the results for CARs I find that returns depend on the average indus-

try announcement reaction in the previous month. Average monthly size and book-to-

market (B/M) adjusted returns are significantly positive 0.266% after months with aver-

age positive industry reactions, and significantly negative 0.454% after months with

average negative industry reactions. The difference of 0.720% is highly statistically

significant and is economically large (8.64% annualized).

Therefore, the evidence indicates a profitable investment opportunity as the in-

dustry-wide information provided by merger announcements does not seem to be incor-

porated into stock prices immediately. This pattern suggests a certain underreaction by

capital markets as past information in the form of the intra-industry effects of merger

announcements in the previous month seem to have an ability to predict the cross-

section of industry returns in the current month. Hence, I examine industry portfolio

investment strategies in order to investigate the profitability of this cross-sectional pat-

tern in industry returns.

Page 57: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

42

Each month, I form portfolios of industries depending on the sign of the average

announcement return, and examine the profits to a zero cost investment strategy taking a

long position in all industries with positive average announcement returns and taking a

short position in all industries with negative announcement returns. The results indicate

that the effect is most pronounced for a one month holding period, where I find a statis-

tically significant return of 1.045% for raw returns (12.54% annualized) and 0.748% for

size-B/M adjusted returns (8.98% annualized). Thereafter, returns decrease steadily with

longer holding periods, though they remain statistically significant. This pattern indi-

cates that the industry return drift is most pronounced at shorter horizons.

The results hold for both the 1980s and the 1990s, while being stronger in the

latter half of the sample period. Across different size quintiles, the effect is more rele-

vant for smaller companies, although it remains statistically significant for all size-

based subsamples. Additional robustness checks confirm the pervasiveness of the effect

across different methodologies. A possible explanation for these findings may be that

the zero cost long-short industry portfolio is not free of factor-related risks, i.e., that the

significant returns represent compensation for risk inherent in those portfolios. How-

ever, when I examine the exposure of the industry portfolio returns to Fama-French

three-factor portfolios in a time-series regression, I do not find support for this hypothe-

sis. Instead, at the one month horizon I find a statistically significant intercept for the

zero cost industry portfolio not explained by exposure to factor-related risks. In a final

test I examine the relation between the cross-section of individual stock returns and av-

erage industry announcement returns. Fama-McBeth regressions show that the average

industry CAR of the previous month is significantly related to individual stock returns

of firms in that industry.

My results indicate that the industry-wide information provided by merger an-

nouncements does not seem to be incorporated into stock prices immediately, a finding

that is apparently at odds with market efficiency in the sense of Fama (1970, 1991).

However, considering the transaction costs associated with monthly portfolio rebalanc-

ing on an industry basis to capture the one month effect, the profitability of the industry

portfolio investment strategies may be called into question. Nevertheless, the effect is

Page 58: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

43

strong and pervasive enough to be of interest for academic researchers as well as market

participants.

The remainder of this essay is organized as follows. Section 3.2 introduces the

data and describes the empirical methodology. Section 3.3 discusses the results and Sec-

tion 3.4 concludes.

3.2 Data and Methodology 3.2.1 Daily Announcement Effects

The data of mergers and acquisitions comes from the Thomson One SDC Platinum Da-

tabase.29 I consider all deals that were announced between January 1, 1985 and Decem-

ber 31, 2002 with an inflation-adjusted transaction value of at least $25 million.30 I as-

sign each transaction to one of 20 industry groups, defined as in Moskowitz and Grin-

blatt (1999), based on the bidder’s SIC code recorded by Thomson at the time of the

announcement.

Daily stock return data is from the daily CRSP files using all stocks identified as

common equity (share code 10 and 11), which excludes all certificates, ADRs, SBIs,

REITs, etc. As in previous studies intra-industry reactions are measured as the stock

market response of an equal-weighted portfolio of all firms within the industry of the

bidder.31 Following Brown and Warner (1985), I use the modified market model to es-

timate abnormal returns. I do not use the market model because, for many industries,

there are months with several merger announcements, which means a high probability

of other bid announcements occurring in the estimation period. Any abnormal returns

29 The mergers and acquisitions section (SDC Platinum) of the Thomson One Banker Database was formerly known as the Securities Data Company’s (SDC) U.S. Mergers and Acquisitions Database.

30 The $25 million cutoff is imposed for 1985 and adjusted for inflation according to the U.S. consumer price index in the following years. I can report, however, that all main results remain qualitatively and quantitatively similar without inflation adjustment.

31 SIC Codes from the CRSP file, which allow for time-series variation in industry classification, are used to assign stocks to industries according to the Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) two-digit classi-fication.

Page 59: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

44

caused by these announcements will bias the estimation.32 I calculate the cumulative

abnormal return (CAR) for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement

date.33 Specifically, the five-day CAR is:

2

2,,]2,2[, )(

ttmtii RRCAR , (3.1)

where Ri,t is industry i’s daily return on date t and Rm,t is the return for the equal-

weighted CRSP index on date t.

For each sample year, Table 3.1 shows the number of deals, the percentage of

the total number of deals during that specific year, as well as the average industry reac-

tion to M&A announcements. Panel A reports the results for the 22,853 deals with a

minimum transaction value of $25 million, Panel B and C display the results for the

16,483 and 11,341 deals with minimum transaction values of $50 million and $100 mil-

lion, respectively. The pattern is similar across all three panels: the two economy-wide

merger waves of the 1980s and 1990s are clearly visible with deal numbers peaking in

1988 and 1998, respectively. Annual average industry announcements effects are con-

sistent with earlier evidence such as Fee and Thomas (2004) and Shahrur (2005): a

slightly positive average around 0.05%. In addition, a certain time pattern can be ob-

served. In general, announcement effects seem to be positive, but towards the peak of

the merger waves they become negative.

32 Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) do not use the market model for the same reasons. Brown and Warner (1980) show that weighting the market return by a firm’s beta does not significantly improve the estimation.

33 The main findings are not susceptible to the choice of the event window length. They also hold for a shorter horizon, such as three days, to estimate CARs.

Page 60: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

Tab

le 3

.1:

Ann

ual D

istr

ibut

ion

of M

&A

Tra

nsac

tions

and

Ave

rage

Indu

stry

Ann

ounc

emen

t Eff

ects

The

sam

ple

cont

ains

all

U.S

. M&

A a

nnou

ncem

ents

bet

wee

n Ja

nuar

y, 1

985

and

Dec

embe

r, 20

02 w

ith a

n in

flatio

n-ad

just

ed tr

ansa

ctio

n va

lue

of a

t lea

st $

25

mill

ion

(Pan

el A

), $5

0 m

illio

n (P

anel

B),

and

$100

mill

ion

(Pan

el C

). Fo

r eac

h ye

ar, t

he ta

ble

show

s th

e nu

mbe

r of d

eals

, the

per

cent

age

of th

e to

tal n

umbe

r of

deal

s dur

ing

that

spec

ific

year

, as w

ell a

s the

ave

rage

indu

stry

reac

tion

to M

&A

ann

ounc

emen

ts d

urin

g th

at y

ear.

The

20 In

dust

ries a

re d

efin

ed a

s in

Mos

kow

itz

and

Grin

blat

t (19

99).

CA

R is

the

cum

ulat

ive

abno

rmal

retu

rn to

the

equa

l-wei

ghte

d in

dust

ry p

ortfo

lio fo

r a fi

ve-d

ay e

vent

win

dow

[-2,

2] a

roun

d th

e an

noun

ce-

men

t dat

e. A

vera

ge In

dust

ry C

AR

den

otes

the

aver

age

CA

R to

the

indu

stry

por

tfolio

at t

he a

nnou

ncem

ent o

f dea

ls th

at ta

ke p

lace

with

in th

at in

dust

ry.

Pane

l A: T

rans

actio

n va

lue

> $

25m

n

Pane

l B: T

rans

actio

n va

lue

> $

50m

n Pa

nel C

:Tra

nsac

tion

valu

e >

$10

0mn

Yea

r N

umbe

r of

Dea

lsA

s % o

f To

tal

Num

ber

Ave

rage

In

dust

ryC

AR

(%)

Num

ber o

f D

eals

As %

of

Tota

lN

umbe

r

Ave

rage

In

dust

ryC

AR

(%)

Num

ber o

f D

eals

As %

of

Tota

lN

umbe

r

Ave

rage

In

dust

ryC

AR

(%)

1985

75

4 3.

340.

074

600

3.64

0.

084

461

4.06

0.09

5 19

86

970

4.30

0.06

877

64.

71

0.07

258

75.

170.

084

1987

93

0 4.

12-0

.034

736

4.47

-0

.034

541

4.77

-0.0

71

1988

1,

197

5.30

0.00

194

75.

75

-0.0

0269

26.

100.

001

1989

1,

040

4.61

0.00

878

34.

75

-0.0

1355

34.

87-0

.023

19

90

657

2.91

-0.0

4646

02.

79

-0.0

4227

62.

43-0

.083

19

91

579

2.56

0.01

940

42.

45

-0.0

0225

82.

27-0

.006

19

92

707

3.13

0.12

749

63.

01

0.12

331

12.

740.

089

1993

92

2 4.

080.

054

621

3.77

0.

044

385

3.39

0.05

0 19

94

1,13

8 5.

040.

121

787

4.77

0.

094

512

4.51

0.10

3 19

95

1,36

9 6.

060.

065

932

5.65

0.

067

610

5.37

0.08

0 19

96

1,70

4 7.

550.

057

1,17

57.

13

0.09

574

56.

560.

127

1997

2,

140

9.48

0.16

71,

541

9.35

0.

185

1,07

49.

460.

182

1998

2,

349

10.4

0-0

.003

1,66

910

.13

-0.0

061,

123

9.89

-0.0

10

1999

2,

011

8.90

-0.0

281,

500

9.10

-0

.044

1,07

69.

48-0

.032

20

00

1,82

4 8.

08-0

.008

1,40

08.

49

0.03

21,

005

8.85

0.02

4 20

01

1,19

6 5.

300.

064

868

5.27

0.

096

603

5.31

0.08

5 20

02

1,09

6 4.

850.

165

788

4.78

0.

162

539

4.75

0.22

0

Tota

lsa

mpl

e 22

,583

10

0.00

0.04

816

,483

100.

00

0.05

211

,351

100.

000.

053

45

Page 61: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

46

3.2.2 Monthly Returns

For the tests of the long-run effects of M&A announcements on industry returns, I use

monthly stock return data from the monthly CRSP files. As for daily returns, industry

portfolio returns are calculated as the equal-weighted average of returns of individual

firms. In addition to raw returns, I calculate size (market capitalization) and book-to-

market equity (B/M) adjusted returns, since much research has documented the ability

of these variables to capture the cross-section of expected returns.34 For book equity, I

use data item 60 (book value of common equity) from Compustat as in Fama and

French (1992).35 I construct characteristic-matched benchmark portfolios by independ-

ently sorting stocks into size and B/M quintiles using NYSE breakpoints. I then inter-

sect those sorts to create 25 portfolios of similar size and B/M. Stocks within each in-

dustry are matched with those well-diversified portfolios based on their size and B/M

characteristic, and the equal-weighted average in excess of these size-B/M benchmarks

represents the monthly industry abnormal return.36

Table 3.2 provides a description of the industry portfolios and summary statis-

tics. The average number of stocks per industry is 290, and the fewest number of stocks

at any time in any industry except Railroads is more than 20. Therefore, virtually all

portfolios are well diversified in that they have negligible firm specific risk. Table 3.2

also reports the average monthly raw returns and size-B/M adjusted returns of the 20

industries.37 F-tests of whether these mean returns differ across industries are not re-

34 See, e.g., Banz (1981), Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1996), and Daniel and Titman (1997). 35 To avoid look ahead bias caused by back filled Compustat data, I include firms only once two com-

plete years of history are available. In addition, I exclude firms with negative book value of equity. 36 Following Fama and French (1992) portfolio compositions are changed each year in July based on a

firm’s size quintile in June of year t and its B/M quintile in December of year t-1. Stock i is then matched with one of the 25 portfolios based on its size and B/M characteristic, and the return of the matched portfolio is subtracted from stock i’s return at time t. I employ this characteristic-matched portfolio adjustment method as opposed to a Fama-French three-factor regression in order to avoid estimation issues regarding factor loadings. Furthermore, Daniel and Titman (1997) find that charac-teristics better capture cross-sectional variation in mean returns than factor loadings.

37 The overall negative average of size-B/M adjusted industry returns implies that stocks from larger industries with more stocks have outperformed stocks from smaller industries with less stocks over the sample period. Table 3.2 confirms this deduction, the four industries with positive adjusted re-turns are among the largest industries.

Page 62: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

47

jected, which suggests that there is little cross-sectional variation in the industry sample

means. Furthermore, t-statistics for the average size-B/M adjusted returns provide little

evidence that unconditional abnormal industry returns exist per se (t-statistics not re-

ported for brevity).

Table 3.2: Industry Summary Statistics Sample statistics of the 20 industry portfolios are reported below, including the two-digit SIC codes used to form the industries as in Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999). The industries are formed monthly from January, 1985 to December, 2002 using CRSP SIC codes, which allow for time variation in industrial classification. The average number of stocks assigned to each industry portfolio every month is reported, along with the minimum number of stocks appearing in each portfolio at any point in time (reported in parentheses). Also reported for each industry over the sample period are the average raw return, the aver-age adjusted return in excess of the size-B/M matched benchmarks, and the monthly average CAR to own-industry M&A announcements with an inflation-adjusted transaction value of at least $25m, $50m, or $100m. CAR is the cumulative abnormal return to the equal-weighted industry portfolio for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. Industry CAR denotes the sample average of the monthly average CAR to each industry portfolio at the announcement of deals that take place within that industry. In addition, the cross-sectional averages of these statistics across industries are reported at the bottom of the table.

Industry SIC Codes

Average Number of Stocks(Minimum)

RawReturns(%)

AdjustedReturns(%)

IndustryCAR(%)$25m

IndustryCAR(%)$50m

IndustryCAR(%)$100m

1. Mining 10-14 273.5 (149) 0.942 -0.130 0.152 0.145 0.0632. Food 20 109.6 (91) 1.091 -0.086 0.031 0.019 0.0043. Apparel 22-23 83.3 (43) 0.572 -0.511 -0.043 -0.063 -0.0604. Paper 26 47.2 (33) 1.108 -0.109 -0.002 -0.045 -0.0085. Chemical 28 320.6 (199) 1.467 0.387 0.059 0.062 0.0036. Petroleum 29 26.1 (21) 1.277 -0.030 -0.036 -0.021 -0.0017. Construction 32 37.9 (23) 1.015 -0.211 -0.050 -0.038 -0.0378. Prim. Metals 33 73.0 (54) 0.766 -0.627 -0.136 -0.119 -0.0899. Fab. Metals 34 105.4 (59) 1.114 -0.185 0.009 0.001 0.05210. Machinery 35 368.5 (261) 1.165 -0.072 0.080 0.066 0.03711. Electrical Eq. 36 449.8 (375) 1.386 0.238 0.040 0.033 0.04112. Transport Eq. 37 94.2 (75) 0.874 -0.194 -0.021 -0.004 -0.00713. Manufacturing 38-39 376.1 (307) 1.274 0.161 0.181 0.175 0.14414. Railroads 40 12.0 (8) 1.226 -0.050 0.043 0.021 0.04615. Transport 41-47 102.4 (76) 1.014 -0.120 0.052 0.046 0.02416. Utilities 49 205.0 (132) 1.028 -0.176 -0.071 -0.060 -0.01117. Dept. Stores 53 39.3 (29) 0.715 -0.168 0.139 0.154 0.17918. Retail 50-52,

54-59 576.3 (429) 0.917 -0.163 -0.012 -0.030 -0.042

19. Financial 60-69 1165.7 (863) 1.318 -0.015 0.054 0.061 0.06820. Other other 1329.1 (957) 1.118 0.079 0.053 0.061 0.064 Average 289.8 (209.2) 1.069 -0.099 0.026 0.023 0.024

F-statistic (identical means) 0.296 1.124 1.382 1.380 1.064 (p-value) (0.999) (0.318) (0.124) (0.125) (0.382)

Page 63: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

48

Finally, Table 3.2 reports average industry CARs for the three different M&A transac-

tion samples with minimum transaction values of $25m, $50m, and $100m, respec-

tively. Similar to adjusted returns there is some cross-sectional variation in returns

across industries visible, but F-tests cannot reject the hypothesis that mean CARs differ.

Hence, there is little evidence that unconditional differences between industry portfolio

returns exist for any of the measures employed.

3.3 Results

In this section I discuss my main empirical findings. Section 3.1 presents evidence on

the persistence in intra-industry effects and the ensuing predictability of monthly indus-

try returns. Section 3.2 discusses the findings related to industry portfolio investment

strategies, and Section 3.3 presents results on the predictability of individual stock re-

turns based on prior intra-industry reactions.

3.3.1 Industry Announcement Effects

3.3.1.1 Persistence in Intra-Industry Effects

Consistent with earlier evidence such as Fee and Thomas (2004) and Shahrur (2005), in

general, industry announcement effects are positive for my samples of M&A transac-

tions. However, Funke et al. (2008) show that industry reactions are only positive at the

beginning of an industry specific consolidation process, but decrease steadily as it con-

tinues and become negative at the end. This pattern is due to increasingly negative com-

petitive effects towards the end of a consolidation process. Hence, time-varying com-

petitive effects of M&A activity, depending on time-varying industry structure, are re-

sponsible for a significant difference in intra-industry reactions over time. However, as

industry structure and therefore the competitive effects of M&A activity change rela-

tively slowly over time, their evidence suggests a certain persistence in intra-industry

announcement reactions, at least at the beginning and end of such industry-specific con-

solidation processes.

Page 64: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

49

I investigate this issue by examining the intra-industry effects of M&A an-

nouncements conditional on the average industry announcement reaction in the previous

month. Table 3.3 reports the median and mean industry CAR to M&A announcements

for three subsamples: (1) industries with a positive average CAR in the previous month,

(2) industries without M&A activity in the previous month, and (3) industries with a

negative average CAR in the previous month.

Table 3.3: Industry Cumulative Abnormal Returns to M&A Announcements The sample contains all U.S. M&A announcements between January, 1985 and December, 2002 with an inflation-adjusted transaction value of at least $25 million (Panel A), $50 million (Panel B), and $100 million (Panel C). CAR i, t denotes the cumulative abnormal return to the equal-weighted industry portfo-lio for a five-day event window [-2,2] around the announcement date. The 20 Industries are defined as in Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999). Average Industry CARi,t-1 denotes the average CAR to the industry portfolio at the announcement of deals that take place within industry i in the previous month t-1. All returns are in percentages, median values are in brackets and absolute t-statistics for mean tests and z-values for median tests in parentheses. The difference tests are based on t-tests for equality of means and a Wilcoxon-test for equality of medians. The final row for each panel lists the number of observations.

All Average Industry CARi,t-1 > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t-1

(2)

Average Industry CARi,t-1 < 0

(3)

Difference ((1)-(3))

Panel A: Transaction value > $25mn

CAR i, t 0.048 0.173 0.030 -0.095 0.268 (%) (5.47) (14.79) (0.65) (7.08) (15.13)

[0.035] [0.140] [-0.0124] [-0.0919] [0.232] (6.99) (18.85) (0.34) (9.48) (19.69)

N 22,583 11,541 1,015 10,027

Panel B: Transaction value > $50mn

CAR i, t 0.052 0.176 0.055 -0.097 0.274 (%) (5.05) (13.34) (1.26) (5.90) (13.10)

[0.036] [0.137] [-0.0019] [-0.0801] [0.217] (6.35) (15.73) (0.65) (7.28) (15.88)

N 16,483 8,351 1,093 7,039

Panel C: Transaction value > $100mn

CAR i, t 0.053 0.160 0.049 -0.070 0.231 (%) (4.31) (9.61) (1.16) (3.52) (8.93)

[0.033] [0.127] [-0.0113] [-0.0764] [0.203] (5.25) (11.75) (0.82) (4.73) (11.42)

N 11,351 5,517 1,089 4,745

Page 65: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

50

The table is split into Panels A, B, and C, which report results for the minimum transac-

tion values of $25m, $50m, and $100m, respectively. I report complete results in the

tables, but limit my discussion to the $50m cut-off sample (Panel B) for expositional

simplicity and due to the similarity of the results.For comparison, the average industry

CAR for all transactions, a significantly positive 0.052%, is reported again. Across the

subsamples (1) through (3), however, the average intra-industry announcement reaction

differs completely: significantly positive average industry CARs of 0.177% can only be

observed if the average industry announcement reaction in the previous month was

positive. Otherwise, if there was no M&A activity in the previous month, the CARs are

not distinct from zero, and if M&A activity in the previous month caused a negative

intra-industry reaction on average, the CARs are significantly negative 0.097%. The

difference between the average industry CAR for subsamples (1) and (3) is a highly

significant 0.274%. The results do not depend on outliers, as the median values reported

in brackets display even more significance.

3.3.1.2 Predictability of Monthly Industry Returns

So far, the evidence clearly suggests that industry CARs depend on the average reaction

to merger announcements in the same industry in the previous month. This finding

raises an interesting question given that average daily industry CARs directly impact

monthly industry returns for that month. Do monthly industry returns differ depending

on the direction of the average announcement reaction in the previous month?

I investigate this question by examining monthly size-B/M adjusted industry re-

turns conditional on the average industry announcement reaction in the previous month.

Table 3.4 reports the mean and median size-B/M adjusted industry returns for the whole

sample as well as the three subsamples from Table 3.3, which are conditional on the

average industry CAR in the previous month. Again, the table is split into Panels A, B,

and C depending on the transaction value, but the discussion is limited to the results for

$50m in Panel B.

Page 66: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

51

Table 3.4: Monthly Industry Size and Book-to-Market Adjusted Returns The sample contains monthly size-B/M adjusted returns of the 20 Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) indus-try portfolios for the period of February, 1985 to December, 2002. Size-B/M Adjusted Industry Return i, tdenotes the equal-weighted portfolio of individually size-B/M adjusted stock returns for all stocks in industry i in month t. Average Industry CARi,t-1 denotes the average CAR to the industry portfolio at the announcement of deals that take place within industry i in month t-1 with transaction values of at least $25mn (Panel A), $50mn (Panel B) and $100mn (Panel C). All returns are in percentages, median values are in brackets and absolute t-statistics for mean tests and z-values for median tests in parentheses. The difference tests are based on t-tests for equality of means and a Wilcoxon-test for equality of medians. The final row for each panel lists the number of observations.

All Average Indus-try CARi,t-1 > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t-1

(2)

Average Indus-try CARi,t-1 < 0

(3)

Difference ((1)-(3))

Panel A: Transaction value > $25mn

-0.098 0.247 -0.061 -0.477 0.725 (2.07) (3.24) (0.61) (6.40) (6.79)

[-0.158] [0.082] [-0.199] [-0.424] [0.506]

Size-B/MAdjustedIndustryReturn i, t (%) (4.33) (1.93) (2.00) (7.22) (6.70)

N 4,300 1,584 1,158 1,558

Panel B: Transaction value > $50mn

-0.098 0.266 -0.116 -0.454 0.720 (2.07) (3.37) (1.35) (5.62) (6.38)

[-0.158] [0.101] [-0.218] [-0.382] [0.483]

Size-B/MAdjustedIndustryReturn i, t (%) (4.33) (2.31) (3.25) (6.35) (6.30)

N 4,300 1,442 1,451 1,407

Panel C: Transaction value > $100mn

-0.098 0.252 -0.142 -0.390 0.643 (2.07) (3.00) (1.89) (4.43) (5.28)

[-0.158] [0.124] [-0.254] [-0.344] [0.467]

Size-B/MAdjustedIndustryReturn i, t (%) (4.33) (2.45) (4.06) (5.27) (5.61)

N 4,300 1,248 1,827 1,225

Overall, size-B/M adjusted returns are unconditionally negative over the sample period,

minus -0.098% with a t-statistic of 2.1.38 However, conditioning on the previous

38 The reported percentage value of -0.098% differs from the value reported in Table 3.2, -0.099%, due to different averaging and a slightly different sample period: the former is the pooled average of all 4,300 monthly industry observations from February, 1985 to December, 2002, while the latter is the cross-sectional average across industries of the time-series average industry size-B/M adjusted re-turns from January, 1985 to December, 2002.

Page 67: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

52

month’s average industry announcement reaction changes the picture completely. Mir-

roring Table 3.3, size-B/M adjusted returns are a significantly positive 0.266% follow-

ing months with positive average industry CARs, and a significantly negative 0.454%

following months with negative average industry CARs. The difference in means of

0.720% is highly statistically significant, and the medians confirm the result with

somewhat less magnitude but similar statistical significance. Finally, the difference in

means also suggests economic importance, as a monthly return of 0.720% points im-

plies an annualized return of 8.64%.

So far, my evidence indicates a profitable investment opportunity as the indus-

try-wide information provided by merger announcements does not seem to be incorpo-

rated into stock prices immediately. This pattern suggests a certain underreaction by

capital markets as past information in the form of the intra-industry effects of merger

announcements in the previous month seem to have an ability to predict the cross-

section of industry returns in the current month. Therefore, I turn to examine industry

portfolio investment strategies in the next section in order to investigate the profitability

of this cross-sectional pattern in industry returns.

3.3.2 Industry Portfolio Investment Strategies

3.3.2.1 Raw and Adjusted Returns

In this section I focus on the question of whether the apparent cross-sectional predict-

ability of industry returns by the average industry announcement effects can be ex-

ploited by sufficiently sophisticated investors. I examine this issue by investigating the

profitability of rolling industry portfolio investment strategies over different holding

periods.

Each month, I assign industries to one of three portfolios depending on the aver-

age CAR in industry i in portfolio formation month t (negative reaction, no M&A, posi-

tive reaction). In addition, I form a self-financing portfolio by taking a long position in

all industries with positive average industry CARi,t and taking a short position in all

industries with negative average industry CARi,t. Then, I calculate returns for longer

Page 68: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

53

horizons using a standard rolling-portfolio method as in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)

and Fama (1998) in order to avoid test statistics that are based on overlapping returns.

For example, suppose I want to look at the performance of industries with posi-

tive average industry CAR over three months. For each calendar month, I calculate

equal-weighted industry returns from individual stock returns for all industries with

positive average industry announcement reaction in the previous month. I then average

the returns for the calendar month across industries to get the return on a portfolio of

positively reacting industries. For the same calendar month, I also calculate the returns

on portfolios of all positively reacting industries from two and three months ago and

average the three resulting portfolio returns. This average tracks the calendar month

performance of an investment strategy that holds a series of portfolios formed in the last

month as well as in the previous two months. I repeat this process every month to get a

time series of returns. I follow the same steps for different horizons (one, three, six, and

12 months after the event), and for other portfolios of industries (positively reacting

industries, industries without M&A, negatively reacting industries, and the self-

financing long-short strategy).

Panel A of Table 3. reports average raw returns for these portfolios and holding

periods. Panel B shows average size-B/M adjusted returns. In addition, time-series t-

statistics are given for the self-financing long-short strategy. The results for the one-

month holding period are as expected given the evidence in Table 3.3. The long-short

strategy earns a significantly positive 1.045% (12.54% annualized) when I employ raw

returns. Using size-B/M adjusted returns leads to a significantly positive 0.748%

(8.98% annualized). For longer horizons the effect is less pronounced. Returns diminish

to 0.619% and 0.458% for the three-month horizon. For the 12-month horizon, they

decrease further to 0.300% and 0.242%, respectively. However, for all holding periods

the results remain statistically significant. Nevertheless, the decreasing pattern of aver-

age returns to the long-short strategy suggests that the apparent industry return predict-

ability is most pronounced at shorter horizons.

Page 69: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

54

Table 3.5: Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns This table shows average monthly returns for rolling industry portfolio investment strategies over differ-ent holding periods. Each month from January, 1985 to December, 2002, industries are assigned to one of three portfolios depending on the average CAR in industry i in portfolio formation month t. Additionally, a self-financing portfolio is formed by going long all industries with positive average industry CARi,t and going short all industries with negative average industry CARi,t. Returns for longer horizons are calcu-lated using a standard rolling-portfolio method as in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) and Fama (1998) to create a time-series of non-overlapping returns. Panel A shows average monthly raw returns and Panel B average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns for one, three, six, and 12-month holding periods. All indus-tries are weighted equally in the portfolio averages, and all months are weighted equally in the time-series average. All returns are in percentages, t-statistics are given in parentheses for the self-financing long-short strategy.

Months after portfolioformation

Average Indus-try CARi t > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t

(2)

Average Indus-try CARi t < 0

(3)

Long-Short Strategy(1)-(3)

t-statistic

Panel A: Average monthly raw returns (%)

1 1.545 1.018 0.500 1.045 (4.92)

3 1.327 1.060 0.707 0.619 (3.54)

6 1.211 1.040 0.795 0.416 (2.93)

12 1.145 0.999 0.845 0.300 (2.78)

Panel B: Average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns (%)

1 0.285 -0.153 -0.462 0.747 (4.42)

3 0.128 -0.094 -0.329 0.458 (3.42)

6 0.063 -0.114 -0.260 0.324 (3.05)

12 0.015 -0.140 -0.228 0.242 (3.03)

Examining both legs of the long-short strategy, we can conclude that both sides seem to

contribute equally to the profitability of the long-short strategy for raw returns. Com-

pared to the portfolio without M&A activity, industries with positive average CARs in

the previous month earn half a percent more at the one month horizon. Portfolios with

negative average CARs earn half a percent less. For the case of size-B/M adjusted re-

turns we can meaningfully look at the statistical significance of the different portfolio

returns. Adjusted returns for industries with positive average CARs in the previous

month are only significantly positive at the one month horizon. However, adjusted re-

turns for industries with negative average CARs in the previous month are significantly

negative up to the 12-month holding period (t-statistics not reported for brevity). This

result suggests that the short leg of the industry portfolio investment strategy is more

Page 70: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

55

important, which indicates that some part of the apparent underreaction by capital mar-

kets to the industry-wide information provided by merger announcements may be due to

market frictions, such as short-selling constraints.

3.3.2.2 Subperiod Analysis

To check whether the results hold across different time periods, I split the sample into

two subperiods. Table 3.6 shows size-B/M adjusted returns for the different industry

portfolios and holding periods for 1985-1993 (Panel A) and for 1994-2002 (Panel B).

Table 3.6: Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns for Time-Period Subsamples This table shows average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns for rolling industry portfolio investment strategies over different holding periods for two time-period subsamples. Panel A reports results for Janu-ary, 1985 to December, 1993. Panel B shows the performance of the portfolios for January, 1994 to De-cember 2004. Each month, industries are assigned to one of three portfolios depending on the average CAR in industry i in portfolio formation month t. In addition, a self-financing portfolio is formed by go-ing long all industries with positive average industry CARi,t and going short all industries with negative average industry CARi,t. Returns for longer horizons are calculated using a standard rolling-portfolio method as in as Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) and Fama (1998). Panel A shows average monthly raw returns and Panel B average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns for one, three, six, and 12-month holding periods. All industries are weighted equally in the portfolio averages, and all months are weighted equally in the time-series average. All returns are in percentages, t-statistics are given for the self-financing long-short strategy.

Months after portfolioformation

Average Indus-try CARi t > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t

(2)

Average Indus-try CARi t < 0

(3)

Long-Short Strategy(1)-(3)

t-statistic

Panel A: Average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns (%) for subperiod 1985-1993

1 0.256 0.135 -0.273 0.529 (3.46)

3 0.156 0.147 -0.200 0.356 (3.96)

6 0.067 0.135 -0.097 0.164 (2.38)

12 0.039 0.099 -0.073 0.112 (2.12)

Panel B: Average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns (%) for subperiod 1994-2002

1 0.329 -0.449 -0.646 0.975 (3.22)

3 0.107 -0.337 -0.469 0.576 (2.25)

6 0.054 -0.355 -0.431 0.485 (2.35)

12 -0.005 -0.366 -0.379 0.374 (2.33)

Page 71: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

56

In terms of time pattern, it is interesting to observe that the profitability of the industry

portfolio investment strategies seems to have strengthened over time. For the first pe-

riod I find a statistically significant size-B/M adjusted return of 0.529% (6.35% annual-

ized) for the long-short strategy, which increases to 0.975% (11.70% annualized) for the

latter period. This may be due to the increasing importance of M&A for corporate

strategies in the 1990s.

3.3.2.3 Size Groups

I employ equal-weighting for monthly returns to be in concurrence with my measure of

short-term intra-industry effects of M&A announcements, the average industry CAR.

This raises the question of whether my findings are only relevant for small, illiquid

stocks, or whether the effect can also be found in large, liquid stocks which are more

accessible for the general investor. I investigate this issue by dividing the sample into

size quintiles.

I divide stocks at the end of each June based on month-end market capitalization

using within-industry NYSE break points. Then, I calculate equal-weighted industry

portfolios from the stocks in the respective quintile. I use within-industry breakpoints to

mitigate the problems associated with splitting industries with a few number of stocks,

such as Petroleum or Railroads, into quintiles.

Table 3.7 shows how the industry portfolio investment strategies perform across

the different size quintiles. There are several patterns to note when comparing the raw

returns to the results reported in Table 3.5. Firstly, the effect indeed seems to be

stronger for smaller stocks. The long-short strategy earns a highly significant return of

1.342% (16.10% annualized) in the smallest quintile at the one-month horizon (Panel

A). It decreases almost monotonically to 0.464% (5.57% annualized) for the largest

quintile (Panel E), but remains statistically significant at the 5% level of confidence.

Secondly, the results confirm that the effect is most pronounced at the shorter horizons,

average raw returns for the long-short strategy at the three, six, and 12-month horizons

are decreasing monotonically, and lose their statistical significance for the largest quin-

tiles.

Page 72: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

57

Table 3.7: Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns for Size-Quintiles This table shows average monthly raw returns for rolling industry portfolio investment strategies over different holding periods for five size quintiles. Stocks are assigned each year to size quintiles based on within-industry NYSE break points for market capitalization as of December of year t-1. Each month from January, 1985 to December, 2002, industries are assigned to one of three portfolios depending on the average CAR in industry i in portfolio formation month t. In addition, a self-financing portfolio is formed by going long all industries with positive average industry CARi,t and going short all industries with negative average industry CARi,t. Returns for longer horizons are calculated using a standard rolling-portfolio method as in as Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) and Fama (1998). Panels A through E show aver-age monthly raw returns for one, three, six, and 12 month holding periods in ascending order for smallest quintiles to largest. All industries are weighted equally in the portfolio averages, and all months are weighted equally in the time-series average. All returns are in percentages, t-statistics are given for the self-financing long-short strategy.

Months after portfolioformation

Average Indus-try CARi t > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t

(2)

Average Indus-try CARi t < 0

(3)

Long-Short Strategy(1)-(3)

t-statistic

Panel A: Average monthly raw returns (%) for quintile 1 (smallest)

1 1.729 1.039 0.387 1.342 (5.74)

3 1.459 1.039 0.669 0.789 (4.07)

6 1.299 1.051 0.799 0.500 (3.24)

12 1.250 1.015 0.890 0.360 (3.28)

Panel B: Average monthly raw returns (%) for quintile 2

1 1.263 1.112 0.365 0.898 (3.77)

3 1.121 1.066 0.593 0.528 (3.12)

6 1.011 0.960 0.662 0.349 (2.74)

12 0.917 0.880 0.673 0.244 (2.49)

Panel C: Average monthly raw returns (%) for quintile 3

1 1.481 0.994 0.525 0.956 (3.95)

3 1.201 0.973 0.783 0.418 (2.21)

6 1.100 0.942 0.841 0.259 (1.78)

12 1.040 0.891 0.820 0.220 (1.99)

Panel D: Average monthly raw returns (%) for quintile 4

1 1.400 1.154 0.854 0.547 (2.61)

3 1.239 1.284 0.948 0.292 (1.89)

6 1.176 1.271 0.964 0.212 (1.75)

12 1.142 1.176 0.975 0.166 (1.78)

Page 73: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

58

Table 3.7 (Continued): Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns for Size-Quintiles

Months after portfolioformation

Average Indus-try CARi t > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t

(2)

Average Indus- try CARi t < 0

(3)

Long-Short Strategy(1)-(3)

t-statistic

Panel E: Average monthly raw returns (%) for quintile 5 (largest)

1 1.329 1.202 0.865 0.464 (2.21)

3 1.249 1.235 0.964 0.285 (1.78)

6 1.192 1.201 0.982 0.209 (1.57)

12 1.131 1.130 0.954 0.178 (1.66)

3.3.2.4 Liquidity Effects

The apparent profitability of the rolling industry portfolio investment strategy, espe-

cially in the smaller size quintiles, raises the question whether it can be explained by

liquidity effects. One way to investigate how liquidity affects the industry portfolio in-

vestment strategies is to exclude those stocks that have high transaction costs. I follow

Chan (2003) and eliminate all stocks with prices of $5 or less from the sample before I

calculate industry returns. Dropping low-priced stocks considerably reduces the number

of stocks underlying the industry portfolios. On average, 30 percent of observations

(stocks in all months) are priced at $5 or below. The remaining sample should consist of

more liquid stocks, since price is related to ease of buying or selling.

Panel A of Table 3.8 reports size-B/M adjusted returns for the rolling industry

portfolio investment strategies based on the reduced set of stocks. The results are simi-

lar to those of Table 3.5. However, the long-short strategy is slightly less profitable with

a return of 0.614% (7.37% annualized) at the one-month horizon. The statistical signifi-

cance, though, is still considerably high, which indicates that the effects of liquidity can

only account for a small portion of the profitability of the industry portfolio investment

strategies.

Page 74: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

59

Table 3.8: Robustness of Monthly Industry Portfolio Returns This table shows average monthly returns for rolling industry portfolio investment strategies over differ-ent holding periods. Each month from January, 1985 to December, 2002, industries are assigned to one of three portfolios depending on the average CAR in industry i in portfolio formation month t. In addition, a self-financing portfolio is formed by going long industries with positive average industry CARi,t and going short industries with negative average industry CARi,t. Returns for longer horizons are calculated using a standard rolling-portfolio method as in as Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) and Fama (1998), and average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns for one, three, six, and 12-month holding periods are reported. All industries are weighted equally in the portfolio averages, and all months are weighted equally in the time-series average. Panel A excludes stocks priced below 5$ before forming industries. Panel B reports returns if only two industries are included each month in the positive and negative average CAR i, t portfo-lios, respectively. These two industries are selected by ranking by formation month average industry CAR i, t and selecting the two portfolios each at the top and bottom of the ranking. The middle portfolio still includes all industries without M&A activity. All returns are in percentages, t-statistics are given for the self-financing long-short strategy.

Months after portfolioformation

Average Indus-try CARi t > 0

(1)

No M&A Activ-ity Industryi,t

(2)

Average Indus-try CARi t < 0

(3)

Long-Short Strategy(1)-(3)

t-statistic

Panel A: Average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns (%) excluding stocks priced < 5$

1 0.223 -0.152 -0.391 0.614 (4.09)

3 0.094 -0.124 -0.280 0.374 (3.27)

6 0.035 -0.143 -0.204 0.240 (2.70)

12 0.011 -0.170 -0.190 0.201 (2.91)

Panel B: Average monthly size-B/M adjusted returns (%) including only two industries on each side

1 0.346 -0.153 -0.535 0.881 (3.18)

3 0.105 -0.094 -0.462 0.567 (2.79)

6 0.094 -0.114 -0.334 0.428 (2.63)

12 -0.011 -0.140 -0.321 0.311 (2.69)

3.3.2.5 Strength of Intra-Industry Effects

Another issue regarding the industry investment strategy is the number of industries

invested in. For all results reported so far, the strategies take a long position in all indus-

tries with positive average industry CAR in the previous month, and a short position in

all industries with negative average industry CAR in the previous month. This corre-

sponds, according to the median, to six industries on each side of the long-short portfo-

lio, with a minimum investment in two industries and a maximum investment in 12 in-

Page 75: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

60

dustries.39 Judging from the standard deviation of the number of industries per portfolio,

which is slightly larger than two, there is substantial variation in what constitutes the

long and short portfolio. In addition, there is substantial variation in average industry

announcement reactions, i.e., in the factor which determines which portfolio an industry

enters. Average industry CARs range from values only marginally different from zero

to values reliably greater or smaller than zero.

Hence, the question arises whether it is possible to increase the profitability of

the rolling industry portfolio investment strategies by only considering a fixed number

of industries for each leg of the trading strategy, and by only considering those indus-

tries with announcement reactions reliably different from zero. I investigate this issue

by only investing in two industries for the long and short portfolio, respectively,40 and

by selecting these two industries from the top and bottom, respectively, of a formation

month ranking on average industry CARs. Panel B of Table 3.8 reports size-B/M ad-

justed returns for these alternative rolling industry investment portfolios.41 Indeed, the

profitability of the long-short strategy improves for all holding periods. At the one-

month horizon, returns increase from 0.748% in Table 3.5 to 0.881% (10.57% annual-

ized), and at the 12-month horizon they increase from 0.242% to 0.311% (3.73% annu-

alized). The majority of the improvement in profitability seems to come from the short

portfolio, while returns to the long portfolio only change considerably at the one-month

horizon. However, the t-statistics for the long-short strategy are lower across all hori-

zons compared to Table 3.5, which indicates that only investing in two portfolios on

each side of the investment strategy increases the time-series variation in the adjusted

returns considerably.

39 On average, the long portfolio consists of 6.71 industries, the portfolio without M&A contains 6.75 industries, and the short portfolio holds 6.54 industries. The standard deviations of the number of in-dustries are 2.20, 2.37, and 2.11, respectively.

40 I select two industries, as it conveniently constitutes not only the top and bottom deciles, but also the minimum number of industries in each portfolio. Results are quantitatively similar when I select a fixed number of three industries, allowing exceptions for months where there are only two industries available.

41 The industry portfolio without M&A activity is unchanged and therefore its returns are identical to Tale 3.5.

Page 76: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

61

3.3.2.6 Three-Factor Risks

In the analysis of size-B/M adjusted returns I already account for the two most impor-

tant factors driving cross-sectional differences in stock returns: size and book-to-market

characteristics. I still find statistically significant returns to the long-short industry strat-

egy unexplained by those characteristics. However, to investigate an alternative choice

of methodology relying on risk factor loadings instead of characteristic-matched returns,

Table 3.9 reports month-by-month alphas and three-factor loadings for the industry

portfolios. These loadings are from a time-series regression of portfolio excess returns

on contemporaneous Fama-French factors in calendar time. Specifically, I regress:

tptptptftmpptftp HMLhSMBsRRbaRR ,,,,, )()()( , (3.2)

where Rp,t is portfolio p’s return t months after formation, for t=(1,3,6,12), and bp, sp,

and hp are the coefficients on the Fama and French (1993) market, size, and book-to-

market portfolio returns from the same calendar months.42 Note that the portfolio re-

turns are unadjusted and non-rolling. I conduct these time-series regressions for the

long-short industry portfolio (Panel A), as well as the individual portfolios with a long

position in all industries with positive average industry CAR (Panel B) and a short posi-

tion in all industries with negative average industry CAR (Panel C). t-statistics are cal-

culated from White (1980) heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors.43

Month-by-month alphas confirm the evidence presented before. The long-short

strategy has a significantly positive intercept of 0.719% one month after portfolio for-

mation. This is due to a significantly positive intercept of 0.537% for the portfolio tak-

ing a long position in all industries with positive average industry CAR, and a signifi-

cantly negative 0.611% for the portfolio taking a short position in all industries with

negative average industry CAR in the previous month.

42 The construction of these portfolio returns is discussed in detail in Fama and French (1993). I thank Kenneth French for providing monthly time-series data for the factors on his website.

43 t-statistics are qualitatively unchanged if I use Newey and West (1987) autocorrelation- and het-eroskedasticity-corrected standard errors at various lags instead of the White (1980) correction.

Page 77: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

62

tppptftmpptftp HMLhSMBsRRbaRR ,,,,, )()()(

Table 3.9: Industry Portfolio Three-Factor Alphas This table shows month-by-month alphas, coefficients, t-statistics, and R² values from a monthly time-series regression where the left-hand side variable is monthly excess returns for a portfolio formed t month ago and the right-hand side variables are contemporaneous Fama and French (1993) market, size, and book-to-market factor mimicking portfolio returns. Industry portfolios are formed each month from January, 1985 until December 2002 by assigning industries to one of three portfolios depending on the average CAR in industry i in portfolio formation month t. In addition, a self-financing portfolio is formed by going long all industries with positive average industry CARi,t and going short all industries with negative average industry CARi,t. Panel A reports the regression results for these long-short industry portfolios, while Panel B presents results for the positive average industry CAR portfolios and Panel C displays the findings for negative average industry CAR portfolios. t-Statistics are based on White (1980) heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors.

Post-formation month Pa (%) Pb (Rm-Rf) Ps (SMB) Ph (HML) R² (%) N

Panel A: Long-Short Industry Portfolio

1 0.719 -0.108 0.182 -0.094 7.24 215 (3.06) (-2.07) (1.24) (-0.81)

3 0.017 -0.063 0.328 0.000 13.86 213 (0.07) (-1.20) (2.44) (-0.00)

6 -0.074 -0.087 0.269 -0.058 13.66 210 (-0.39) (-2.02) (2.98) (-0.53)

12 -0.001 0.020 0.117 -0.176 9.72 204 (-0.01) (0.38) (1.25) (-1.60)

Panel B: Positive Industry CAR Portfolio

1 0.537 0.927 0.830 0.309 84.29 215 (3.32) (23.84) (9.57) (4.46)

3 0.194 0.964 0.926 0.342 84.58 213 (1.19) (23.63) (9.98) (3.90)

6 0.030 0.976 0.853 0.383 85.99 210 (0.21) (22.51) (11.39) (4.76)

12 0.192 1.008 0.776 0.273 76.70 204 (0.92) (20.12) (6.96) (2.80)

Panel C: Negative Industry CAR Portfolio

1 -0.611 1.036 0.656 0.411 78.97 215 (-3.45) (22.24) (5.89) (4.06)

3 -0.250 1.028 0.607 0.350 79.95 213 (-1.48) (24.17) (6.09) (3.39)

6 -0.320 1.064 0.593 0.449 79.87 210 (-1.74) (30.51) (6.29) (5.10)

12 -0.226 0.990 0.668 0.457 83.15 204 (-1.47) (26.95) (11.32) (6.31)

Page 78: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

63

In contrast to the next-month regressions, all month-by-month alphas for three, six and

12 months after portfolio formation are not significantly different from zero at conven-

tional levels of confidence.44 This confirms the earlier conclusion that the industry re-

turn predictability by intra-industry announcement effects is most pronounced at the

shorter horizon.

3.3.3 The Cross-Section of Individual Stock Returns

The main objective of this essay relates to the study of long-term industry returns after

M&A announcements, depending on the initial intra-industry effects of the announce-

ment. I find that the short-term announcement reaction has an ability to predict the

cross-section of future industry returns in the sense that a self-financing long-short

strategy buying industries with positive average industry CARs and selling industries

with negative average industry CARs yields significantly positive profits not accounted

for by known risk factors. But as industry returns are calculated directly from individual

stock returns, an alternative question arises: does the average announcement reaction to

M&A have any predictive power for the cross-section of expected individual stock re-

turns? I investigate this issue as an additional robustness check on the results with an

alternative methodology.

Specifically, I use Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions to de-

termine the impact of average industry announcement CARs controlling for factors

known to predict stock returns. Each month from 1985 to 2002, I regress the cross-

section of individual stock returns over one, three, six and 12-month horizons on a con-

stant and various past firm characteristics. I then average the coefficients across months,

and calculate standard errors from the time-series of coefficients. In regressions where

individual stock returns over several months are employed as dependent variable, I use

Newey and West (1987) autocorrelation-robust standard errors with a lag equal to the

number of months over which the returns overlap. The set of independent variables in-

44 The longer-horizon evidence is most consistent for the short portfolio, where all intercepts are nega-tive and the six-month intercept is significant at the 10 percent level of confidence.

Page 79: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

64

cludes: market ,45 size (log of market capitalization of month t-1), book-to-market (log

of book-to-market ratio calculated using past data as in Fama and French (1992)), sev-

eral past individual stock return variables (last month’s return, ret-1:-1, last years return

from t-12 to t-2, ret-12:-2, as well as the return from t-36 to t-13, ret-36:-13), as well as last

month’s industry announcement reaction (average industry CAR of month t-1).

The results on the control variables reported in Table 3.10 confirm previous

findings in the literature. The use of market , size and book-to-market as regressors

allows to capture their ability, if any, to explain the cross-section of expected stock re-

turns. The one-month past return controls for liquidity and microstructure effects docu-

mented by Jegadeesh (1990) which induce a reversal in short-term stock returns. The

nearest year of returns captures the Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) momentum effect, and

the long-run return the De Bondt and Thaler (1985) three- to five-year reversal effect.

However, for my purposes the coefficient on the average industry CAR in month t-1 is

of main interest: at the one-month horizon is positive and highly statistically significant,

with a t-statistic of over seven. For the regressions with longer-horizon returns the pre-

dictive ability of the average industry CAR is somewhat less reliable as t-statistics de-

crease substantially, but the influence remains positive and the coefficients are still sig-

nificant, at least at the 5 percent level. This ability of the past month’s average industry

CAR to predict the cross-section of individual stock returns confirms the earlier evi-

dence on differences in long-term industry returns after observing the initial intra-

industry effects and provides strong evidence affirming the robustness of the results.

45 Market s are estimated by regressing the prior 36 months of excess returns for each stock on a con-stant and the past 36 months of excess returns of the CRSP value-weighted index. Stocks are then ranked based on their coefficient estimates from this regression (pre-ranking betas) and assigned to one of 100 groups based on this ranking. Stocks within a particular beta group are assigned the equal-weighted average beta for that group. This is essentially the procedure employed by Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) in their Table VI.

Page 80: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

65

Table 3.10: Fama/MacBeth Regressions for Individual Stock Returns Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions are run every month on the universe of securities from February 1985 to December 2002. Specifically, the cross-section of individual stock returns over one, three, six, and 12-month horizons are regressed on a constant and a host of firm characteristics: mar-ket (estimated using the prior 36 months of returns), size (log of market capitalization at month t-1), B/M (log of book-to-market ratio calculated using past data as in Fama and French (1992)), several past return variables, as well as the average industry CAR of month t-1. Time series t-statistics are in brackets, below each average coefficient. Newey and West (1987) heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation-robust standard errors are used in all calculations for the three, six, nine and 12-month regressions.

Hori-zon Intercept ˆ ln(Size) ln(B/M) ret-1:-1 ret-12:-2 ret-36:-13

Average IndustryCARt-1

AverageR² (%)

1 0.0228 0.0008 -0.0009 0.0000 -0.0661 0.0310 -0.1588 0.5036 5.34(3.05) (0.48) (1.46) (0.02) (12.02) (1.25) (4.75) (7.07)

3 0.0684 0.0017 -0.0026 -0.0006 -0.0061 0.0485 -0.4816 0.4917 5.56(3.27) (0.39) (1.64) (0.19) (0.88) (0.90) (4.20) (2.54)

6 0.1406 0.0041 -0.0054 -0.0010 0.0096 -0.0491 -0.9129 0.7572 5.79(4.06) (0.53) (2.00) (0.17) (0.88) (0.43) (4.11) (2.15)

12 0.2154 0.0091 -0.0081 -0.0020 0.0164 -0.2538 -1.3609 0.9855 5.90(4.59) (0.80) (2.15) (0.21) (1.16) (1.54) (3.98) (2.39)

3.4 Conclusion

Most studies that measure the intra-industry effects of M&A transactions show that ri-

vals experience significantly positive abnormal returns when the industry consolidates.

In a recent study, however, Funke et al. (2008) show that these positive industry reac-

tions are not pervasive over time. At the beginning of an industry-wide consolidation

process intra-industry effects are significantly positive. However, due to increasing

competition, they decrease steadily and become negative at the end of such a consolida-

tion process. Hence, time-varying competitive effects of M&A activity, depending on

time-varying industry structure, are responsible for a significant difference in intra-

industry reactions over time. However, as industry structure and therefore the competi-

tive effects of M&A activity change relatively slowly over time, this suggests a certain

persistence in intra-industry announcement reactions.

Page 81: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

66

I confirm this implication by documenting that industries which experience posi-

tive average announcement reactions continue to do well at future merger announce-

ments, while industries that experience negative average announcement reactions con-

tinue to do poorly. These differences in short-term announcement reactions directly im-

pact monthly industry returns, resulting in a difference in monthly returns of 0.720%

(8.64%) between industry groups depending on the direction of the previous month’s

average industry reaction. Industry portfolio investment strategies, which buy positively

reacting industries and sell negatively reacting industries, appear profitable even after

controlling for size and book-to-market effects in returns. Profitability has strengthened

over time and seems to exist also for the largest stocks. The findings cannot be ex-

plained by liquidity effects or exposure to three-factor risks. Additional robustness

checks with Fama-McBeth regressions confirm the ability of the past month’s average

industry announcement reaction to predict the cross-section of stock returns.

In this essay I document a strong and prevalent drift in long-term industry re-

turns after M&A announcements. The evidence suggests that capital markets underreact

to the industry-wide information provided by merger announcements.

Page 82: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

67

4 Predictability of Supplier Returns After Large Customer

Price Changes

Abstract

This essay documents return predictability across stocks, specifically from customers to

their suppliers. I extend the investigation of Cohen and Frazzini (2006), who examine

monthly return predictability for economically linked firms, to analysis at the daily level

and show that for large positive (negative) customer price change events supplier stock

prices experience significantly positive (negative) cumulative abnormal returns for up

to 20 days after the event. However, the major part of these returns arises in the first

five days and such return predictability cannot be observed for the largest stocks and

the most recent time period, indicating that capital markets are relatively efficient in

incorporating extreme customer return shocks into supplier stock prices. Hence, limited

investor attention to information on economically linked firms seems to be less severe

for the attention-grabbing events investigated in this essay.

I thank my co-authors Timo Gebken and Lutz Johanning, as well as Yakov Amihud, Julie Ng, Gas-ton Michel, Dirk Schiereck, Sebastian Werner, and Felix Zeidler for valuable comments and insights. Any remaining errors are mine.

Page 83: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

68

4.1 Introduction

Limited investor attention (investor inattention) and its consequences for information

processing in capital markets have recently generated a lot of interest in the asset pricing

literature.46 In a new paper Cohen and Frazzini (2006) examine economically linked

firms and document widespread cross-asset return predictability in U.S. capital markets.

They conclude that investors do not take into account ex-ante available and often long-

standing customer-supplier relationships due to their limited attention, so that prices of

supplier firms have a predictable lag in updating to new information about its customer

firms.

I examine this apparently wide-spread return predictability across assets further.

Specifically, my interest lies in the short-run return dynamics at the daily horizon not

examined by Cohen and Frazzini (2006) who base their study of supplier-customer rela-

tionships on monthly returns. I want to know more precisely for how long return pre-

dictability from customer to supplier firms can be observed, and to which extent this

return predictability is also visible in the extremes of the return distribution.

In the light of this, I focus on extreme daily customer price changes, i.e., events

which should grab investor’s attention due to related underlying news or by becoming

news themselves. In this situation, I want to know whether we can still observe supplier

return predictability due to limited investor attention to the consequences of this cus-

tomer stock return information for supplier prices. Alternatively, I hypothesize that

given such attention-grabbing customer events, limited attention is less of an issue for

the related supplier firms and cross-asset return predictability could be relatively short-

lived.

My results show that this is the case. I use publicly available customer informa-

tion from firms’ financial statements to build my database on customer-supplier rela-

46 Recent empirical works on limited attention, among others, include Hong, Lim and Stein (2000), Hou and Moskowitz (2005), Hou, Peng and Xiong (2006), Menzly and Ozbas (2006), Cohen and Frazzini (2006), Hou (2007) and Hong, Torous and Valkanov (2007). In addition, Gervais, Kaniel and Mingelgrin (2001), Barber and Odean (2006), and Frazzini and Lamont (2006) examine shifts in in-vestor attention and their price effects. See the literature review in Section 4.2.

Page 84: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

69

tionships.47 Using an event study framework and daily stock returns from 1981 to 2004,

I investigate abnormal supplier stock returns after large abnormal customer price

changes, i.e., a daily customer abnormal stock return three standard deviations or more

from the mean. I show that after such large customer price changes there is indeed some

supplier return predictability: after large positive events supplier 20-day cumulative

abnormal returns (CAR) are statistically significant positive 0.569% and after large

negative events supplier 20-day CAR amount to statistically significant negative

0.372%.

However, this supplier return predictability mainly stems from the first week af-

ter the event: for positive events about half of the 20-day CAR arises over the [t+1,t+5]

window, and for negative events return predictability is completely attributable to these

five trading days. This finding is interesting given the somewhat contrary evidence in

Cohen and Frazzini (2006) who document a drift between economically linked firms at

the monthly horizon. However, Cohen and Frazzini (2006) examine differences between

quintile portfolios, while I look farther into the tails of the distribution examining ex-

treme return events. I surmise that my different finding arises as capital markets incor-

porate large abnormal customer price changes more quickly into supplier stock prices.

Limited investor attention may be grabbed by such large price changes and shifted rela-

tively quickly to the importance of this customer information for supplier stock prices.

To shed more light on this finding I investigate the best proxy for limited inves-

tor attention in my research setting: the initial supplier reaction to the large abnormal

customer price change. I show that if there is a large positive (negative) contemporane-

ous supplier reaction to a positive (negative) large customer price change, markets seem

to have already incorporated all information immediately and no post-event supplier

drift can be discerned. However, if there is no reaction or even a negative (positive)

reaction to a positive (negative) large customer price change, I document a drift in sup-

plier stock prices in the same direction as the customer event. Sometimes, investors

47 Currently, FASB regulation SFAS No. 131 governs segment reporting in the U.S. and requires nam-ing customers which account for 10 percent or more of a firm’s sales.

Page 85: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

70

seem to shift their limited attention not immediately to this customer stock return infor-

mation but incorporate it only slowly into supplier prices.

I investigate the robustness of my results in several respects. First, I show that

my findings are not due to industry effects, given the findings of Hou and Moskowitz

(2005) and Hou (2007) who demonstrate that lead-lag effects among stocks are primar-

ily an industry phenomenon. I show that supplier return predictability also exists across

industries and when excluding the smallest supplier decile. When I examine the impor-

tance of size, I find that supplier return predictability disappears in the largest supplier

size tertile, consistent with the notion that limited investor attention is a more important

issue for smaller supplier firms. This finding is intuitive given the greater news cover-

age larger firms receive, and taking into account prior evidence on the importance of

firm size for return predictability. Hence, the effects of limited attention for asset prices

are more important for smaller firms. In addition, I examine the stability of the return

predictability over time and show that, at least for large negative customer price

changes, supplier return predictability has completely disappeared in the more recent

part of my sample period.

Overall, my finding of only very short-run supplier return predictability for the

tails of the customer return distribution extends the existing literature on limited inves-

tor attention. We know from empirical evidence that there exists a widespread return

predictability across assets in capital markets (Menzly and Ozbas (2006), Cohen and

Frazzini (2006), Hong, Torous and Valkanov (2007)) at odds with market efficiency in

the sense of Fama (1970, 1991), most likely due to limited investor attention and capac-

ity constraints in information processing. However, investor attention is only ‘partially

limited’ when examining the large, attention-grabbing customer price changes investi-

gated in this essay: return predictability mainly occurs in the first week after the event,

does not apply to the largest supplier stocks, and has disappeared, at least for negative

events, in the more recent past.

The remainder of this essay is organized as follows. Section 4.2 gives an over-

view of the related literature on the effects of limited investor attention on asset prices.

Page 86: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

71

Section 4.3 introduces the customer-supplier data and describes the research methodol-

ogy. Section 4.4 discusses the empirical results and Section 4.5 concludes.

4.2 Related Literature

Limited investor attention is a phenomenon which has recently generated a lot of re-

search interest in the asset pricing literature. The psychology literature acknowledged

that attention is a scarce cognitive resource as early as Kahneman (1973), who proposed

a psychological model of divided attention which is based on the idea of mental efforts.

In his model, cognitive resources are allocated accommodating differing mental re-

quirements by different tasks, and attention to one specific task requires the substitution

of mental resources from another task.48 In the asset pricing literature, Merton (1987)

provides the first rigorous theoretical approach to limited investor attention with a

model where investors restrict their information gathering and trading to a small subset

of all available stocks. As a result, given asymmetry in the amount of information about

any stock, those with less information available are less recognized by investors, have a

smaller investor base, and trade at a greater discount due to the inability of their inves-

tors to appropriately share the risks of these stocks (neglected stocks).

More recently, Hong and Stein (1999) propose a model with two boundedly ra-

tional investor types in which information diffuses slowly across the investment public

and in which return predictability ensues from investors failing to rationally extract all

available information from market prices. Hirshleifer and Teoh (2003) model firms’

choices between alternative means of presenting financial information in accounting

reports and the resulting effects on market prices when investors have limited attention

and processing power. Peng (2005) provides a model analyzing the effects of capacity

constraints in the learning processes of investors. Finally, Peng and Xiong (2006) de-

velop a model investigating investors’ attention allocation, their ensuing learning behav-

ior given limited attention, and the resulting effects on asset price dynamics.

48 For summaries of the psychology literature see also Nisbett and Ross (1980) and Pashler (1998).

Page 87: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

72

Building on these theoretical models, a growing body of literature is examining

empirical evidence on limited investor attention. Huberman and Regev (2001) provide a

particularly obvious case in point: a firm’s stock price soaring in the wake of a New

York Times article on a potential development of new cancer-curing drugs. However,

this potential breakthrough in cancer research had been reported in the journal Nature

and in various popular newspapers (including The Times) more than five months earlier.

In a broader empirical investigation, Hou and Moskowitz (2005) study the severity of

market frictions affecting a stock using the delay with which its price responds to new

information. They show that frictions associated with investor recognition appear to be

related to this delay effect. Hou (2007) finds that slow diffusion of common information

is the main reason for such lead-lag effects and that it is mainly an intra-industry phe-

nomenon: big firm returns lead small firm returns in the same industry.

Hong, Lim and Stein (2000) investigate momentum in stock returns to test the

gradual-information-diffusion model of Hong and Stein (1999) and find that firm-

specific information, especially negative information, diffuses only slowly across inves-

tors. Hou, Peng and Xiong (2006) examine the implications of investor attention for

both price momentum and earnings momentum (post-earnings announcement drift).

They show that variation in trading volume, which they use as a proxy for attention,

causes significant variation in abnormal returns to both price momentum and earnings

momentum.49

Besides these works on the effects of limited attention, there is a strand of litera-

ture examining shifts in investor attention due to events such as earnings announce-

ments or firm-specific news. Barber and Odean (2006) use different attention proxies,

i.e., stocks appearing in the news, stocks with high abnormal trading volume, and stocks

with extreme one-day returns, and show that individual investors are net-buyers of such

attention-grabbing stocks. They also document that institutional investors are less prone

to attention-driven purchases. Frazzini and Lamont (2006) examine scheduled earnings

49 The original finding that price momentum varies with trading volume is due to Lee and Swaminathan (2000).

Page 88: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

73

announcement dates and show that, on average, stock prices rise around these dates

concurrent with an increase in volume. They suggest that this apparent ‘earnings an-

nouncement premium’ is driven by small investor buying and the resulting price pres-

sure when the announcement brings these stocks to their attention. Gervais, Kaniel and

Mingelgrin (2001) use a similar argument to explain their finding of a return premium

to stocks with an abnormal increase in trading volume: they propose that shocks to the

trading activity of a stock affect its visibility, and therefore the demand and price for

that stock.

Recent papers on limited attention related to this essay are Menzly and Ozbas

(2006) and Hong, Torous and Valkanov (2007). Menzly and Ozbas (2006) document a

cross-momentum effect among industries which are related to each other along the sup-

ply chain. They show that a profitable industry momentum strategy can be constructed

based on upstream and downstream industry returns.50 Hong, Torous and Valkanov

(2007) show that the returns of industry portfolios are able to predict the movements of

stock markets, for the U.S. and international equity markets. They attribute their finding

of cross-asset return predictability to slow information diffusion across markets and

limited investor attention to information from markets the investors do not specialize in.

Finally, the paper by Cohen and Frazzini (2006) is most closely related to my

work. They take a new approach to investigating limited investor attention and slow

information diffusion by focusing on a more intuitive link between stocks: firm-specific

customer-supplier relationships. They create a long-short customer momentum strategy

which yields monthly alphas of over 1.5%. Therefore, they conclude that stock prices

do not promptly incorporate news about economically related firms, leading to return

predictability across assets. Naturally, the customer-supplier link provides an excellent

framework for testing limited investor attention. Given U.S. disclosure requirements on

major customers, these links are publicly available to all investors, and they do have

real effects on cash flows (Cohen and Frazzini (2006)).

50 They document that their results are different from individual stock momentum (Jegadeesh and Tit-man (1993)) and industry momentum (Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999)).

Page 89: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

74

However, Cohen and Frazzini (2006) focus on return predictability using

monthly data in an asset pricing framework and do not investigate short-run effects on

the daily level. This leaves some important research questions unanswered which I ad-

dress in this essay: do we observe such cross-asset return predictability only at a

monthly horizon taking all customer information into account? Or do we also observe it

on a daily basis in an event-study framework using only selected customer-supplier

events? How long does it take, exactly, for customer stock return information to be in-

corporated into supplier stock prices?51 The event study approach also provides the op-

portunity to study the more extreme cases of return predictability: i.e., really large cus-

tomer price changes in the tail of the return distribution and the ensuing supplier stock

price reaction.

Such a setting provides an ideal ground to test limited investor attention: if we

can observe supplier return predictability after extreme attention-grabbing customer

price changes, then we can reasonably assume a violation of market efficiency due to

investor inattention to relevant, publicly available information. However, if we can find

no or limited evidence of supplier return predictability after such large customer price

changes, we can conclude that investor inattention to customer information is restricted

to the smaller price changes studied by Cohen and Frazzini (2006) at the monthly hori-

zon.52 This seems plausible as the news driving such extreme customer performance

will catch the attention of some investors, while the large price change itself will catch

the attention of others. Even in the absence of any information, extreme price changes

can become news themselves and generate investor attention (Barber and Odean

(2006)). This leaves the question to be answered empirically: will this attention to the

customer result in an efficient market reaction for suppliers, or can we observe supplier

51 Another question Cohen and Frazzini (2006) do not address is long-term performance beyond the monthly horizon. This may be an avenue for further research, however, keeping in mind the accom-panying asset pricing model specification problems.

52 Cohen and Frazzini (2006) study return differences between quintile portfolios. Assuming a normal distribution, the extreme quintile portfolios have a distance of 0.84 standard deviations from the cen-ter of the distribution.

Page 90: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

75

return predictability due to particularly obvious limited investor attention? I will inves-

tigate this issue in the following sections.

4.3 Data and Methodology 4.3.1 Customer-Supplier Relationships

I want to investigate return predictability across assets to examine the extent of investor

limited attention. My empirical analysis is based on long-standing important customer-

supplier relationships between firms. The data on such relationships is taken from the

Compustat segment files and covers the period from 1980 to 2004. U.S. regulation re-

quires publicly listed firms to report information on operating segments in their share-

holder reports.53 Most interesting for this study, firms are required to disclose informa-

tion on any major customer accounting for more than 10% of total sales. This allows me

to identify suppliers and their customers in the merged CRSP/Compustat database. For

the analysis I only use common equity (share codes 10 and 11), which excludes all cer-

tificates, ADRs, SBIs, REITs, etc.

However, the customer identification process is rather tedious: customer identi-

ties are listed in the segment files without unique identifiers such as CRSP’s PERMNO

or Compustat’s GVKEY. The database only contains company name abbreviations be-

fore 1998 and full names afterwards. In addition, the full names do not always corre-

spond exactly to the names listed in the CRSP/Compustat files, and both full names and

abbreviations vary across reporting firms and throughout the years. Therefore, I use a

visual inspection procedure to link the customers to the corresponding PERMNO identi-

fier. First, for the pre-1998 data, I visually compare the abbreviations used in the

Compustat segment files to all company names listed on CRSP. In cases in which visual

inspection determines an almost certain, distinct match, I link the abbreviation with the

corresponding PERMNO identifier. Second, for the post-1998 data, I automatically link

53 Since December 15, 1997, FASB regulation SFAS No. 131 governs segment reporting. From 1977 until 1997, regulation SFAS No. 14 required segment disclosure.

Page 91: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

76

full names from the Compustat segment files which exactly match company names

listed on CRSP with the corresponding PERMNO identifier. Next, I visually compare

the remaining unmatched full names to all company names listed on CRSP and link the

corresponding entries whenever I find a unique match. Finally, all customers without a

unique match are excluded from the sample. However, some discretion is involved in

matching name abbreviations and full names with firm identities, so I am deliberately

conservative in assigning firm identifiers. I choose to exclude firms which are only

probable matches because I recon that the statistical noise generated by mistakenly iden-

tifying unrelated firms as customers is greater than the noise associated with failing to

identify actual customers.

Finally, following Cohen and Frazzini (2006) I use the standard time lag im-

posed to match accounting variables with subsequent return data and, therefore, impose

a six month lag between fiscal yearend customer-supplier information and matched

stock returns. My final sample has 11,641 unique customer-supplier relationships with

33,711 distinct annual customer-supplier relationships. I draw confidence in the match-

ing precision from the fact that I am reasonably close to the 11,484 unique customer-

supplier relationships reported by Cohen and Frazzini (2006) over the same time period.

4.3.2 Large Abnormal Customer Price Changes

My daily stock price and return data is from CRSP. A daily customer stock return that

represents a large abnormal price change is called an event. A change is deemed to be

‘large’ if the abnormal return after subtracting the value-weighted CRSP index is more

than three standard deviations above or below the mean. Mean and standard deviation

are calculated over rolling windows comprising the preceding 250 trading days. I follow

Pritamani and Singal (2001) in using such a relative standard deviation based approach

as opposed to an absolute percentage cutoff as I believe that this is more appropriate for

my research objective.54 In order to ensure that I do not include multiple events in the

54 Since a constant percentage price change, say 10%, may be important or not depending on the vola-tility of a customer stock, it appears preferable to use a relative standard deviation based cutoff. The distance of three standard deviations follows Pritamani and Singal (2001). Table 4.3, however, also re-

Page 92: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

77

same time period for the same firm, I require customer firms not to have a large abnor-

mal price change over the preceding 20 trading days. Events are restricted to lie on or

between January 2, 1981 and December 2, 2004 to reserve the last 20 trading days in

2004 for examining post-event performance.

I match all such large abnormal price change by a customer with the respective

supplier stock return data. As I am interested in examining only genuinely delayed sup-

plier stock price reactions due to limited investor attention, and not the effects of infre-

quent trading or other market microstructure issues, I impose certain requirements on

these suppliers. First, I exclude all events where the supplier had a closing price of less

than $5 on the event date. Low price stocks usually have high transaction costs, making

it more difficult to incorporate all relevant information.55 Second, I require suppliers to

have positive volume on each of the 60 days preceding the event date. This ensures that

infrequently traded stocks are excluded from the sample. Third, I require the supplier to

have positive volume on the event day itself. This last screen ensures that I only include

supplier stocks which actually traded on the day of the large abnormal price change by

the customer, i.e., stocks which could have reacted to this change contemporaneously.56

The final sample consists of 26,021 events.

I divide this sample into positive and negative events depending on the sign of

the event day customer abnormal return. Of the 26,021 events, the return is significantly

positive for 15,369 events and significantly negative for 10,652 events.57 Table 4.1 pro-

vides summary statistics on the sample. On average, there are 640 positive and 444

negative events per year, with as little as 118 and 22 events and as many as 1,323 and

ports the results for more extreme price changes using four standard deviations as distance. Further-more, I can report that my results remain qualitatively similar using an absolute cut-off of similar magnitude such as 8%, 10% or 12%.

55 I chose the threshold of $5 to be consistent with Cohen and Frazzini (2006). However, I can confirm that my results are qualitatively similar using a screen of $10 as in Pritamani and Singal (2001).

56 Of course, we do not observe intraday dynamics in these price changes and the corresponding sup-plier reactions. Hence, there will be some supplier stocks that did not trade anymore after witnessing a large abnormal price change by their customer towards the end of the trading day. To this extent the market reaction may be deemed efficient even if it only occurs on the next trading day.

57 This preponderance of large positive price changes is also reported by Pritamani and Singal (2001) in the same relative proportions of 3 to 2.

Page 93: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

78

905 events in a given year, respectively. Interestingly, for both subsamples only roughly

23% of suppliers are in the same industry as their customer based on the 48 industries of

Fama and French (1997). This finding mitigates any concerns that I may only be pick-

ing up intra-industry effects, an issue that will be examined in more detail in Section

4.4.3.

Table 4.1: Summary Statistics This table shows summary statistics for the annually pooled time series of events as well as the com-pletely pooled sample. The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns (AR) three standard deviations above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier between January 1981 and December 2004. The customer abnormal return is the customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. Panel A shows statistics for positive events and Panel B for negative events.

Panel A: Positive Events Panel B: Negative Events

Mean Me-dian

Min Max S.D. Mean Me-dian

Min Max S.D.

Number of events per year 640 564 118 1323 348 444 442 22 905 238

Number of suppli-ers per year 328 294 72 652 160 264 247 20 470 125

Number of cus-tomers per year 464 417 92 1090 250 348 339 18 784 200

% of supplier-customer in same industry

23.5 23.7 15.0 28.8 3.7 23.2 22.9 16.8 32.4 4.6

Customer abnor-mal return (%) 8.4 6.5 1.6 216.0 6.5 -8.8 -6.8 -88.7 -2.2 6.3

Events per customer 5.8 3.0 1.0 37.0 6.5 4.6 2.0 1.0 29.0 5.1

Events per supplier 6.2 3.0 1.0 83.0 7.9 4.8 3.0 1.0 45.0 5.5

Number of suppli-ers per customer 4.6 1.0 1.0 193.0 13.8 4.7 1.0 1.0 185.0 13.5

Number of cus-tomers per supplier 1.8 1.0 1.0 17.0 1.3 1.7 1.0 1.0 14.0 1.2

% of sales to customer 19.1 14.0 0.0 600.0 17.6 19.2 14.0 0.0 330.7 17.0

Examining the statistics on all observations pooled, on average, event day customer

abnormal returns are a significantly positive 8.4% for positive events and significantly

negative 8.8% for negative events, with considerable variation resulting in a standard

deviation of 6.5% and 6.3%, respectively. The minimum value for positive events of

Page 94: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

79

1.6% and the maximum value of -2.2% for negative events indicate that the standard

deviation based cut-off procedure clearly allows ‘large’ price change events in low-

volatility customer firms to be relatively ‘small’ in absolute terms.

For positive events (negative events), on average, there are 5.75 (4.56) events

per customer and 6.23 (4.76) events per supplier, with as many as 37 (29) events per

customer and 83 (45) per supplier. Turning to supplier-customer relationships, there are,

on average 4.56 (4.74) unique suppliers per customer and 1.79 (1.71) unique customers

per supplier over the whole time span, with as many as 193 unique suppliers per cus-

tomer and 17 unique customers per supplier. This indicates that some very large cus-

tomer firms, such as General Motors, IBM, Wal-Mart, Ford, or AT&T, have a huge

number of different suppliers, an issue which I take up in the robustness tests in Section

4.4.6. However, the median customer firm is only linked to one supplier and the median

supplier firm is only linked to one customer. On average, 19% of supplier sales go to

each customer, with as little as zero (missing values) and as much as 100%.

4.3.3 Post-Event Abnormal Supplier Returns

To measure abnormal returns, cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) are computed for an

equal-weighted portfolio of supplier firms for up to 20 days following a customer event.

I choose a 20-day period to be able to capture the short-run stock return dynamics fol-

lowing large abnormal customer price changes. I am interested in examining the speed

of supplier price adjustments given limited attention to such customer stock return in-

formation at the monthly horizon as discovered by Cohen and Frazzini (2006). There-

fore, my choice of a 20-day period covers one trading month. To be able to examine the

stock return dynamics more precisely, I report results for various periods up to 20 days,

but focus my discussion on the 20-day period.

Page 95: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

80

Daily abnormal returns itAR are calculated as the daily supplier stock return less

the average return to a size-matched control portfolio.58 The control portfolios are

equal-weighted size decile portfolios. Deciles are determined at the beginning of each

year using NYSE size breakpoints. The control portfolio return and breakpoint data is

from Ken French’s homepage.59 Abnormal returns are then simply calculated as the

difference:

tstiti RRAR ,,, (4.1)

where tiR , is the daily return for each supplier i in the sample and tsR , is the respective

size quintile s return on day t . Post-event cumulative abnormal returns ]20,1[,iCAR for

the 20-day window are then simply calculated as the sum: 20

1,]20,1[,

ttii ARCAR (4.2)

The statistical significance of these CARs is then gauged from the cross-sectional mean

and standard deviation over positive and negative events separately. Alternatively, to

assure the robustness of the results I also calculate buy-and-hold abnormal returns

(BHAR) as follows: 20

1,

20

1,]20,1[, )1()1(

tts

ttii RRBHAR (4.3)

Table 4.2 reports some annual descriptive statistics. For conciseness, the discussion is

limited to the positive events displayed in Panel A; the results for negative events

shown in Panel B are largely similar. The table shows that there is considerable varia-

tion in the number of events per year, with as little as 118 events in a low-volatility pe-

riod such as 1981 and a many as 1,323 events in a high volatility period such as 2000.

Furthermore, event-day average customer abnormal returns also show substantial varia-

tion ranging from as low as 5.08% in 1989 to as much as 17.64% in 2001. Interestingly,

58 Opposed to customer abnormal returns, the precise model for measuring supplier abnormal returns does matter regarding my research objective. I follow Pritamani and Singal (2001) in choosing a size-matched control portfolio approach to capture any size effect in returns.

59 I thank Ken French for supplying this data. My results are not susceptible to alternative control port-folios: I reach qualitatively similar conclusions using size quintiles or calculating control portfolio re-turns myself.

Page 96: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

81

contemporaneous average supplier abnormal returns are positive in each single year and

reach their maximum simultaneously with average customer abnormal returns in 2001

at 3.52%.

Furthermore, an important feature of the data is immediately visible from the ta-

ble: by construction (due to the reporting requirements) customer firms are, on average,

substantially larger than supplier firms. This raises the question whether I may be pick-

ing up lead-lag effects from large to small stocks as documented by Lo and MacKinlay

(1990) and recently shown to be a within-industry phenomenon by Hou and Moskowitz

(2005) and Hou (2007). Alternatively, I could be picking up some short-term version of

the industry momentum effect found by Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999). Therefore,

this issue will be addressed in the analysis of industry effects in Section 4.4.3. However,

it should not play an important role in explaining my results as 77% of the customer-

supplier relationships are across industries as reported in Table 4.1.

Page 97: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

Tab

le 4

.2:

Ann

ual D

escr

iptiv

e St

atis

tics

The

sam

ple

cont

ains

all

larg

e cu

stom

er a

bnor

mal

ret

urn

shoc

k ev

ents

, def

ined

as

cust

omer

abn

orm

al r

etur

ns (

AR

) th

ree

stan

dard

dev

iatio

ns a

bove

(po

sitiv

e ev

ents

) or b

elow

(neg

ativ

e ev

ents

) the

mea

n, w

hich

can

be

mat

ched

with

an

econ

omic

ally

-link

ed s

uppl

ier b

etw

een

Janu

ary

1981

and

Dec

embe

r 200

4. T

he c

us-

tom

er a

bnor

mal

retu

rn is

the

cust

omer

raw

retu

rn m

inus

the

CR

SP v

alue

-wei

ghte

d re

turn

, its

mea

n an

d st

anda

rd d

evia

tion

are

estim

ated

ove

r rol

ling

250-

day

win

dow

s. Fo

r eac

h ye

ar, t

he ta

ble

show

s th

e nu

mbe

r of e

vent

s, ev

ent d

ay a

vera

ge a

bnor

mal

retu

rn, s

tock

pric

e, a

nd s

ize

(mar

ketc

apita

lizat

ion)

for c

usto

mer

s an

d as

wel

l as t

heir

resp

ectiv

e su

pplie

rs, f

or b

oth

posi

tive

(Pan

elA

) and

neg

ativ

e (P

anel

B) c

usto

mer

retu

rn sh

ocks

. The

supp

lier a

bnor

mal

retu

rn is

the

supp

lier

raw

retu

rn m

inus

the

resp

ectiv

e eq

ual-w

eigh

ted

size

-dec

ile p

ortfo

lio.

Pa

nel A

: Pos

itive

Eve

nts

Pane

l B: N

egat

ive

Even

ts

C

usto

mer

Ave

rage

Supp

lier A

vera

ge

Cus

tom

er A

vera

ge

Su

pplie

r Ave

rage

Yea

r N

umbe

r of

Eve

nts

AR

(%)

Pric

e ($

)Si

ze

($m

)A

R(%

)Pr

ice

($)

Size

($

m)

Num

ber

of E

vent

sA

R(%

)Pr

ice

($)

Size

($

m)

AR

(%)

Pric

e($

)Si

ze

($m

)

1981

11

8 7.

13

30.0

62,

884

0.21

23.4

138

322

-5.8

642

.38

3,33

90.

1717

.90

223

1982

33

8 6.

26

35.3

29,

292

0.34

20.8

338

714

7-6

.56

31.3

92,

568

0.03

21.0

435

119

83

223

8.09

43

.32

4,22

00.

5421

.73

249

184

-7.0

350

.44

10,2

83-0

.36

19.8

225

919

84

236

7.85

36

.02

2,34

70.

7217

.75

266

301

-6.0

044

.04

10,4

56-0

.50

19.3

736

1 19

85

434

6.31

49

.92

9,20

60.

3621

.32

474

291

-5.6

960

.35

12,0

17-0

.31

20.9

465

1 19

86

758

5.83

56

.20

12,1

090.

2824

.24

766

446

-5.4

356

.62

19,1

06-0

.01

23.2

673

519

87

971

6.07

62

.63

20,1

600.

1022

.59

703

511

-6.6

446

.52

12,4

04-0

.80

18.7

884

119

88

178

8.62

43

.51

9,33

20.

4719

.37

615

161

-7.4

354

.25

16,9

76-0

.63

17.2

345

719

89

643

5.08

52

.79

19,8

640.

1722

.80

1,38

129

2-5

.66

55.6

518

,717

-0.3

620

.55

1,01

119

90

518

6.29

41

.65

15,1

770.

3018

.82

701

486

-6.2

242

.58

18,4

66-0

.08

20.9

91,

664

1991

40

6 8.

67

38.5

410

,340

0.75

22.0

086

230

8-7

.44

48.7

019

,471

-0.4

420

.53

798

1992

58

0 7.

43

42.4

818

,020

0.04

21.9

31,

236

327

-9.4

447

.80

19,8

47-0

.31

19.8

661

3 19

93

837

7.17

45

.57

24,6

320.

4221

.10

1,12

446

9-7

.03

43.9

419

,509

-0.4

920

.98

1,01

9 19

94

823

7.65

43

.10

21,9

480.

2519

.82

911

490

-7.4

941

.06

19,3

43-0

.46

20.9

71,

002

1995

82

7 7.

20

49.2

725

,592

0.75

23.0

71,

118

715

-6.9

750

.76

32,3

34-0

.95

23.1

91,

131

1996

1,

182

8.46

55

.19

25,9

620.

3720

.20

747

739

-9.3

544

.75

30,8

75-0

.66

21.3

01,

357

1997

1,

181

8.21

55

.69

44,3

550.

2822

.84

1,18

782

9-8

.10

56.7

936

,990

-0.3

723

.61

1,28

919

98

1,12

5 8.

79

54.2

642

,963

0.22

21.3

11,

350

780

-8.8

052

.32

43,0

91-0

.51

21.3

41,

775

1999

89

1 10

.31

60.0

984

,226

0.79

25.6

12,

465

567

-10.

7558

.91

66,5

25-0

.53

23.8

03,

347

2000

1,

323

12.1

2 53

.33

102,

380

1.02

28.4

72,

768

905

-15.

1044

.63

88,6

11-1

.29

26.9

94,

790

2001

43

9 17

.64

26.0

244

,129

3.52

17.9

32,

237

380

-14.

4832

.96

44,3

89-2

.44

20.9

42,

089

2002

54

7 11

.70

28.4

060

,289

1.26

18.0

12,

299

689

-10.

1132

.98

66,2

60-0

.57

19.4

41,

829

2003

39

9 10

.00

31.2

723

,071

0.60

20.3

02,

372

437

-10.

1037

.03

69,7

93-0

.17

20.5

63,

437

2004

39

2 7.

42

43.9

484

,996

0.53

21.3

22,

993

176

-9.4

833

.57

33,7

77-0

.80

19.1

51,

333

All

15,3

69

8.44

48

.76

37,1

720.

5522

.15

1,35

510

,652

-8.7

946

.95

37,4

79-0

.61

21.7

01,

694

82

Page 98: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

83

4.4 Results4.4.1 Large Abnormal Customer Price Changes

Panel A of Table 4.3 reports post-event supplier abnormal returns for large abnormal

customer price changes using a three standard deviations cut-off definition as discussed

in the prior section. There is a significant contemporaneous supplier reaction: average

abnormal returns are 0.552% for positive events and -0.613% for negative events, both

highly statistically significant. This contemporaneous reaction to the large abnormal

customer price changes is followed by drift in the directions predicted: on average, sup-

pliers experience statistically significant CARs of 0.569% and -0.372%, respectively,

over the 20-day post-event window. However, this drift appears to be rather short-lived,

as among the shorter windows only the [t+1,t+5] window shows CARs statistically sig-

nificant at the one percent level.60

This finding is interesting given the evidence in Cohen and Frazzini (2006) who

document a drift between economically linked firms at the monthly horizon. Using a

different methodology to discover short-run supplier return dynamics, I document

somewhat contrarily that capital markets seem to react rather quickly to the information

contained in large abnormal customer price changes, as they do not show statistically or

economically significant drift for windows more than a week after the event. However,

Cohen and Frazzini (2006) examine differences between quintile portfolios, while I

look farther into the tails of the distribution, namely three standard deviations from the

mean.61 Such extreme customer price changes can be considered as attention-grabbing

events (Barber and Odean (2006)), after which the (limited) investor attention is appar-

ently relatively quickly shifted onto the importance of such customer stock return in-

formation for supplier stock prices. I conjecture that this is the reason why the major

part of the supplier return predictability I uncover occurs within the first five days fol-

lowing the large customer price change.

60 I also checked for any continuing drift beyond the 20-day post-event window, but did not find any significant effects.

61 For a normal distribution of returns, the extreme quintile portfolios have a distance of 0.84 standard deviations from the center of the distribution.

Page 99: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

84

Table 4.3: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers after Customer Return Shocks The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns (AR) three standard deviations (Panel A) and four standard deviations (Panel B) above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier between January 1981 and December 2004. The customer abnormal return is the customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. The table shows the number of events, average event day customer abnormal return, as well as supplier cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) for different post-event windows. The supplier ab-normal return is calculated as the supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-decile portfolio. t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A: 3 S.D. Distance Panel B: 4 S.D. Distance

Events: Positive Negative Positive NegativeSample Size: 15,369 10,652 5,901 4,944Customer AR (%): 8.436 -8.792 12.016 -12.289 (160.16) (-143.27) (101.58) (-108.65)Trading Day Supplier CAR (%)

t+0 0.552 -0.613 0.614 -0.733 (14.61) (-14.28) (9.18) (-10.88)

t+1 0.231 -0.192 0.218 -0.265 (7.02) (-4.59) (3.86) (-3.97)

t[+1,+5] 0.236 -0.432 0.452 -0.505 (3.56) (-4.92) (4.14) (-3.61)

t[+6,+10] 0.065 0.026 0.124 0.005 (0.97) (0.31) (1.07) (0.04)

t[+11,+15] 0.175 0.022 0.084 0.207 (2.63) (0.27) (0.76) (1.68)

t[+16,+20] 0.093 0.012 0.157 -0.048 (1.43) (0.15) (1.49) (-0.37)

t[+1,+20] 0.569 -0.372 0.817 -0.340 (4.49) (-2.40) (3.92) (-1.41)

Panel B of Table 4.3 reports the results for even larger abnormal customer price changes

four standard deviations from the mean. The number of events is reduced substantially

to 5,901 positive and 4,944 negative events. The findings, however, are largely similar:

return predictability seems to be limited to the post-event window [t+1,t+5] with a sig-

nificantly positive drift of 0.452% and a significantly negative drift of 0.505%, respec-

tively. In addition, we can observe for both panels that a large part of the post-event

reaction occurs immediately on the day after the event. This supports my conclusion

that capital markets incorporate large abnormal customer price changes fairly quickly

into supplier stock prices as (limited) investor attention is grabbed by the large customer

Page 100: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

85

price changes, and relatively quickly shifted onto the importance of this customer in-

formation for supplier stock prices.

4.4.2 Contemporaneous Supplier Reactions

This first finding, however, warrants some detailed scrutiny. Intuitively, the contempo-

raneous supplier reaction on the event day itself plays a crucial role in determining the

amount of post-event drift to expect from supplier firms and can be regarded as the best

proxy for investor attention in this setting: if there is a large positive (negative) contem-

poraneous supplier reaction to a large positive (negative) customer price change, it is

very likely that markets have already incorporated all information immediately and no

post-event supplier drift is to be expected. However, if there is no reaction or even a

negative (positive) reaction to a positive (negative) large customer price change, I ex-

pect a drift in supplier stock prices in the same direction as the customer event as inves-

tors slowly shift their limited attention to this customer stock return information and

incorporate it into supplier prices.

Table 4.4 shows exactly this picture: Panel A shows CARs after positive events

for supplier tertiles sorted on their event day abnormal return. The supplier tertile with

the highest abnormal return, i.e., a positive 4.727%, shows no significant positive post-

event day drift. On the contrary, the tertile with the lowest abnormal return, i.e., a nega-

tive 3.195%, shows considerable drift in the same direction as the customer price

change: a highly statistically significant 1.144% for the 20-day post-event window. The

middle tertile with almost no reaction on the event day itself also shows positive drift

with a statistically significant positive CAR of 0.409%.

The results in Panel B for negative events confirm the findings from Panel A:

the supplier tertile with the lowest abnormal return, i.e., a negative 4.745%, shows no

significant negative post-event drift, while the tertile with the highest abnormal return,

i.e., a positive 3.369%, shows a statistically significant negative CAR of 0.685% for the

20-day post-event window. Overall, the picture is consistent with the hypothesis stated

above: supplier firms who show the largest (smallest) contemporaneous reaction to the

Page 101: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

86

large positive (negative) customer price change subsequently show no discernible return

predictability, and vice versa.

Table 4.4: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers Conditional on Initial ReactionThe sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns three standard deviations above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier between January 1981 and December 2004. The cus-tomer abnormal return is the customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. The table shows the number of events, average event day customer abnormal return, as well as supplier cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) for different post-event windows and subsamples based on event day supplier abnormal return (AR). The supplier abnormal return is calculated as the supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-decile portfolio. Panel A shows the results for positive events, and Panel B for negative events. t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A: Positive Events Panel B: Negative Events

Event Day Supplier AR:

LowestTertile Tertile 2 Highest

TertileLowestTertile Tertile 2 Highest

Tertile

Sample Size: 5,123 5,123 5,123 3,551 3,550 3,551Customer AR (%): 8.425 7.595 9.288 -9.852 -7.864 -8.659 (93.73) (96.58) (90.95) (-84.74) (-83.11) (-83.09)Trading Day Supplier CAR (%)

t+0 -3.195 0.124 4.727 -4.745 -0.462 3.369 (-75.71) (16.09) (67.98) (-75.09) (-46.83) (59.51)

t+1 0.370 0.103 0.219 -0.104 -0.276 -0.197 (5.92) (2.39) (3.48) (-1.21) (-4.89) (-2.72)

t[+1,+5] 0.666 0.117 -0.076 -0.099 -0.439 -0.758 (5.43) (1.25) (-0.61) (-0.58) (-3.55) (-4.82)

t[+6,+10] 0.146 0.028 0.020 0.258 -0.160 -0.020 (1.16) (0.30) (0.16) (1.51) (-1.37) (-0.13)

t[+11,+15] 0.256 0.146 0.123 -0.048 0.064 0.049 (2.07) (1.56) (0.98) (-0.30) (0.58) (0.35)

t[+16,+20] 0.076 0.117 0.086 -0.205 0.199 0.044 (0.63) (1.22) (0.72) (-1.26) (1.68) (0.30)

t[+1,+20] 1.144 0.409 0.154 -0.094 -0.336 -0.685 (4.81) (2.30) (0.65) (-0.31) (-1.50) (-2.51)

4.4.3 Within- and Cross-Industry Effects

An issue already raised in the discussion in Section 4.3.3 is the discrepancy in size: cus-

tomer firms are substantially larger than supplier firms. Lo and MacKinlay (1990) re-

port lead-lag effects from large to small stocks. Recently, Hou (2007) shows that the

lead-lag effect is an intra-industry phenomenon: stock returns on big firms lead returns

Page 102: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

87

on small firms within the same industry. He argues that slow diffusion of common in-

formation is a leading cause of this lead-lag effect. Table 4.5 investigates whether my

results are simply picking up such intra-industry lead lag effects or if we can also ob-

serve return predictability for supplier-customer relationships across industries. There-

fore, I split my sample into across industry (customer and supplier are in different in-

dustries) and within industry (customer and supplier are in the same industry) subsam-

ples. Industries are defined using the 48 industries from Fama and French (1997), and

given the evidence in Table 4.1 the distribution of events is as expected: 78% happen

across industries and 22% within industries.

Table 4.5: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers Within and Across Industries The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as abnormal returns (AR) three standard deviations above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier between January 1981 and December 2004. The Customer abnormal return is the customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. The table shows the number of events, average event day customer abnormal returns, as well as supplier cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) for different post-event windows across industries (customer and supplier in different industries) and within industries (customer and supplier in the same industry). The supplier abnormal return is calculated as the supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-decile portfolio. Panel A shows the results for all events, and Panel B excluding suppliers in the smallest size decile. t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A: Including Smallest Size Decile Panel B: Excluding Smallest Size Decile

Across Industries Within Industries Across Industries Within Industries

Events: Pos. Neg. Pos. Neg. Pos. Neg. Pos. Neg.Sample Size: 11,676 8,122 3,561 2,441 9,252 6,487 3,049 2,064Customer AR (%): 8.289 -8.694 8.855 -9.070 8.349 -8.773 8.716 -9.071 (138.46) (-126.67) (80.53) (-66.09) (120.17) (-112.39) (73.90) (-58.87)Trading Day Supplier CAR (%) 0 0.434 -0.484 0.954 -1.027 0.471 -0.534 0.977 -1.130 (10.21) (-10.01) (11.39) (-10.89) (10.13) (-10.08) (10.96) (-11.15)

+1 0.173 -0.144 0.422 -0.357 0.162 -0.120 0.391 -0.322 (4.60) (-3.01) (6.08) (-3.99) (3.93) (-2.27) (5.35) (-3.38)

[+1,+5] 0.110 -0.464 0.642 -0.342 0.181 -0.434 0.588 -0.264 (1.46) (-4.55) (4.54) (-1.95) (2.20) (-3.90) (3.95) (-1.43)

[+6,+10] 0.070 0.060 0.041 -0.095 0.041 0.037 0.113 -0.010 (0.91) (0.60) (0.29) (-0.55) (0.49) (0.34) (0.73) (-0.06)

[+11,+15] 0.101 0.065 0.442 -0.076 0.066 0.073 0.404 -0.084 (1.32) (0.70) (3.14) (-0.46) (0.79) (0.73) (2.67) (-0.48)

[+16,+20] 0.101 -0.029 0.097 0.142 0.131 -0.018 0.112 0.170 (1.35) (-0.30) (0.71) (0.84) (1.59) (-0.17) (0.76) (0.95)

[+1,+20] 0.381 -0.369 1.223 -0.370 0.419 -0.342 1.217 -0.188 (2.64) (-2.05) (4.55) (-1.18) (2.63) (-1.74) (4.25) (-0.57)

Page 103: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

88

Panel A reports the results for all suppliers. For negative events, the 20-day post-event

CAR is comparable for both subsamples: across industries it amounts to a statistically

significant -0.369%, while within industries it is an insignificant -0.370%.62 For positive

events, post-event return predictability is larger within industries: the 20-day CAR is a

highly significant 1.223% within industries. However, across industries it still amounts

to a significant 0.381%. Following intuition, within industries the information link be-

tween customers and suppliers is closer as the contemporaneous reaction is about twice

as large as across industries. This observation may also help to explain the higher drift

after positive events within industries: firstly, it is more likely that I have correctly

matched customers and, therefore, face less statistical noise, and secondly, customer

stock return information may simply be more important within industries than across

industries. Notwithstanding, we can conclude that the supplier return predictability

arises also independent of the within-industry lead-lag effect reported by Hou (2007).

However, Hou (2007) argues that this lead lag effect results from a lead of big

firms over small firms. Therefore, Panel B shows the results excluding the smallest sup-

plier size decile.63 The results do not change the conclusion from Panel A. Return pre-

dictability after positive events is stronger within-industries, but also statistically sig-

nificant across industries. Overall, I conclude from this exercise that the within-industry

lead-lag effect documented by Hou (2007) is not responsible for my findings of short-

run return predictability across economically linked stocks, as we do observe it across

industries and excluding the smallest supplier stocks.

4.4.4 Size Groups

Independent of the aforementioned discussion the influence of supplier size warrants a

more detailed investigation. There is widespread evidence in the asset pricing literature

that the information incorporation process in capital markets depends on firm size. Fur-

62 The difference in significance can be attributed to the substantially higher number of cross-industry events.

63 Obviously, how many small firms to exclude is arbitrary. My results are qualitatively similar if I exclude the two smallest deciles.

Page 104: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

89

thermore, it is reasonable to assume that investor inattention may vary with firm size as

larger firms are more likely to be covered by analysts or to be mentioned in the news.

Therefore, Table 4.6 reports post-event CARs for different supplier size tertiles. For

positive events in Panel A, return predictability can only be observed for the first two

tertiles: the smallest and middle tertile show significantly positive 20-day post-event

CARs of 0.446% and 0.945%, while the largest tertile only experiences an insignificant

CAR of 0.337%. The results are similar for negative events in Panel B, only the first

two tertiles experience significantly negative CARs of 0.389% and 0.578%, while the

largest tertile shows no post-event return predictability.

Table 4.6: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers for Different Size Groups The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns (AR) three standard deviations above (positive events in Panel A) or below (negative events in Panel B) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier between January 1981 and December 2004. The customer abnormal return is the customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. The table shows the number of events, average event day customer abnormal retrun, as well as supplier cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) for different post-event windows and subsamples based on beginning-of-year supplier market capitalization. The supplier abnormal return is calculated as the supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-decile portfolio. t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Panel A: Positive Events Panel B: Negative Events

Supplier Size: Smallest Tertile Tertile 2 Largest

TertileSmallest

Tertile Tertile 2 Largest Tertile

Sample Size: 8,538 4,334 2,497 5,847 3,049 1,756Customer AR (%): 8.385 8.627 8.279 -8.662 -9.157 -8.590 (122.95) (81.33) (63.85) (-112.09) (-71.38) (-57.17)Trading Day Supplier CAR (%)

t+0 0.416 0.689 0.782 -0.432 -0.766 -0.950 (7.97) (9.39) (10.09) (-7.23) (-10.07) (-9.19)

t+1 0.275 0.216 0.104 -0.192 -0.276 -0.047 (5.91) (3.55) (1.56) (-3.31) (-3.57) (-0.49)

t[+1,+5] 0.203 0.286 0.262 -0.538 -0.288 -0.329 (2.17) (2.34) (1.89) (-4.36) (-1.74) (-1.83)

t[+6,+10] 0.075 0.107 -0.041 0.123 0.043 -0.326 (0.80) (0.86) (-0.29) (1.01) (0.28) (-1.73)

t[+11,+15] 0.158 0.318 -0.013 0.012 -0.067 0.206 (1.65) (2.67) (-0.09) (0.11) (-0.47) (1.15)

t[+16,+20] 0.011 0.234 0.130 0.014 -0.266 0.492 (0.11) (1.99) (0.95) (0.12) (-1.75) (2.71)

t[+1,+20] 0.446 0.945 0.337 -0.389 -0.578 0.044 (2.53) (3.87) (1.33) (-1.77) (-2.02) (0.14)

Page 105: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

90

Given these findings I conjecture that larger supplier stocks incorporate the information

contained in large abnormal customer price changes immediately into their stock prices

and, therefore, show no discernible post-event drift, due to the higher attention investors

give to large stocks. This conjecture is supported by the observation that the largest size

quintiles also show the largest contemporaneous stock price reaction on the event day

itself. Hence, I conclude that limited attention is more severe for small- and mid-cap

stocks, a finding which is not surprising.

4.4.5 Time-Period Subsamples

Another question frequently asked by studies on return predictability concerns the sta-

bility of the relationship over time. Can we observe increasingly efficient information

processing or does limited attention to customer stock return information persevere until

today? In Table 4.7, I address this issue by dividing the sample into three eight-year

time periods.

It is immediately visible that return predictability after negative events has dis-

appeared over time: the 20-day CAR for negative events is highly significantly negative

for the first period from 1981 to 1988 at a large 1.869%, but declines to values indistin-

guishable from zero for the more recent time periods from 1989 to 1996 and 1997 to

2004. For positive events, no such change in the relationship can be observed: the 20-

day CAR is statistically significant positive for all three periods at 0.510%, 0.675%, and

0.501%, respectively.

In addition, an increase in the contemporaneous reaction to large customer price

changes is visible over time, which is consistent with a more efficient incorporation of

customer return information into supplier stock prices in current capital market condi-

tions. Hence, I conjecture that the short-term return predictability arising from limited

attention to large customer price changes has largely disappeared, at least for negative

events. This may be due to a decrease in the preponderance of investor inattention,

maybe arising from more rapidly shifting investor attention given modern-day commu-

nication systems or from exploitation by arbitrageurs. Apparently, at least large negative

Page 106: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

91

customer price changes do not cause return predictability for supplier stock prices any

more.

Table 4.7: Abnormal Returns to Suppliers for Different Sample Periods The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns (AR) three standard deviations above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier for three eight-year time periods: Jan 1981 to Dec 1988, Jan 1989 to Dec 1996, Jan 1997 to to Dec 2004. The customer abnormal return is the customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. The table shows the number of events, average event day customer abnormal return, as well as supplier cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) for different post-event windows. The supplier abnormal return is calculated as the supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-decile portfolio. t-statistics are reported in parentheses.

Time Period: Jan 1981 – Dec 1988 Jan 1989 – Dec 1996 Jan 1997 – Dec 2004

Events: Positive Negative Positive Negative Positive NegativeSample Size: 3,256 2,063 5,816 3,826 6,297 4,763Customer AR (%): 6.510 -6.233 7.325 -7.555 10.458 -10.894 (78.84) (-71.16) (101.57) (-81.75) (109.42) (-108.37)Trading Day Supplier CAR (%) t+0 0.299 -0.392 0.379 -0.525 0.843 -0.779 (5.25) (-4.35) (7.70) (-8.78) (11.32) (-10.63)

t+1 0.215 -0.684 0.225 -0.160 0.244 -0.005 (3.95) (-7.40) (4.99) (-2.77) (3.90) (-0.07)

t[+1,+5] 0.191 -1.580 0.321 -0.253 0.180 -0.079 (1.76) (-8.69) (3.65) (-2.13) (1.41) (-0.52)

t[+6,+10] 0.145 0.141 0.114 0.078 -0.022 -0.065 (1.41) (0.80) (1.24) (0.68) (-0.17) (-0.44)

t[+11,+15] 0.209 -0.340 0.286 0.204 0.056 0.032 (2.04) (-2.34) (3.23) (1.80) (0.43) (0.23)

t[+16,+20] -0.035 -0.091 -0.046 -0.073 0.287 0.126 (-0.35) (-0.62) (-0.50) (-0.61) (2.31) (0.87)

t[+1,+20] 0.510 -1.869 0.675 -0.043 0.501 0.013 (2.71) (-6.93) (3.96) (-0.19) (2.02) (0.05)

4.4.6 Robustness Tests

I conduct further subsample tests to ensure my results are robust. First, I restrict my

sample to those suppliers for which the customer information should matter most: i.e., I

only consider suppliers for whom at least 20% of their sales goes to the respective cus-

tomer. For these, the link to the customer should matter most, implying both a larger

contemporaneous stock price reaction, as well as a larger post-event return predictability

Page 107: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

92

given the increased importance of the customer stock return information for the supplier

firm. Panel A of Table 4.8 shows that this is indeed the case. CARs for the 20-day event

window amount to a marginally significant positive 0.513% after positive events64 and a

highly significant negative 0.966% after negative events. So at least for negative events,

supplier return predictability is increased when considering suppliers with the closest

links to the respective customers.

Table 4.8: Robustness Tests The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns (AR) three standard deviations above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier. The customer abnormal return is the cus-tomer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, its mean and standard deviation are estimated over rolling 250-day windows. The table shows the number of events, average event day customer ab-normal return, as well as supplier cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) for different post-event windows. The supplier abnormal return is calculated as the supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-decile portfolio. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. Panel A restricts the sample to those suppliers which sell at least 20% to the respective customer. Panel B excludes all events for the five customer firms with the highest number of suppliers. Panel C shows supplier buy-and-hold abnormal returns (BHAR) instead of CAR for the post-event windows.

Panel A: Panel B: Panel C:Sales to Customer>20% Excl. Top 5 Customers Supplier BHAR

Events: Positive Negative Positive Negative Positive NegativeSample Size: 3,236 2,297 11,488 8,246 15,369 10,652Customer AR (%): 8.132 -8.675 9.336 -9.449 8.436 -8.792(t-statistic) (79.87) (-71.41) (138.64) (-125.99) (160.16) (-143.27)Supplier CAR (%) (t-statistic)0 0.790 -0.750 0.688 -0.689 0.552 -0.613

(9.57) (-7.49) (14.85) (-13.93) (14.61) (-14.28)

+1 0.244 -0.430 0.254 -0.254 0.231 -0.192(3.37) (-4.53) (6.35) (-5.40) (7.02) (-4.59)

[+1,+5] 0.188 -0.550 0.224 -0.456 0.199 -0.469(1.24) (-2.82) (2.81) (-4.54) (2.97) (-5.43)

[+6,+10] 0.161 -0.121 -0.007 -0.023 0.050 -0.021(1.00) (-0.63) (-0.09) (-0.24) (0.74) (-0.24)

[+11,+15] 0.243 -0.172 0.140 -0.006 0.152 -0.020(1.66) (-0.96) (1.74) (-0.06) (2.27) (-0.25)

[+16,+20] -0.079 -0.124 0.116 0.014 0.062 -0.001(-0.55) (-0.68) (1.48) (0.14) (0.94) (-0.01)

[+1,+20] 0.513 -0.966 0.472 -0.471 0.392 -0.731(1.74) (-2.87) (3.10) (-2.64) (2.95) (-4.58)

64 The decrease in statistical significance is due to the substantially decreased sample size, which is reduced by 80%.

Page 108: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

93

Second, I investigate an issue already raised in Section 4.3.2: the influence of very large

customer firms, such as General Motors, IBM, Wal-Mart, Ford, or AT&T, who have a

huge number of different suppliers. Therefore, I exclude all events for the five customer

firms with the highest number of suppliers as they are responsible for 25% of events, a

clearly influential share for such a small number of customers. However, Panel B of

Table 4.8 offers reassurance that the findings are robust as the results are comparable to

the full sample: after positive events I find a significantly positive CAR of 0.472%, and

after negative events I find a significantly negative CAR of 0.471%.

Third, I take an investors perspective and examine post-event BHARs instead of

CARs. However, Panel C shows that this methodical choice does not affect my findings

much, as there is a significantly positive BHAR of 0.392% after positive events and a

significantly negative BHAR of 0.731% after negative events for the 20-day window.

Hence, given the results of theses robustness tests, I conclude that my findings are quite

reliable.

4.4.7 Cumulative Abnormal Return Regressions

Finally, the question remains how cross-sectional differences in customers and suppliers

interact to determine the supplier post-event CARs. To address this issue Table 4.9 re-

ports event-time regressions of the 20-day supplier CARs on a constant and supplier and

customer characteristics. The base regression equation takes the form:

tititjititjtti SUPPSIZEWITHININDSUPPARCUSTARCAR ,,4,,3,2,10]20,1[, (4.4)

where ]20,1[, ttiCAR is the supplier cumulative abnormal return over the post-event win-

dow [t+1,t+20], tjCUSTAR , is the event-day abnormal return for the respective cus-

tomer, tiSUPPAR , is the event day supplier abnormal return, tiSUPPSIZE , is the natural

logarithm of its market value of equity, and tjiWITHININD ,, a dummy taking the value

of one if supplier and customer are in the same industry and zero otherwise, all for sup-

plier i and its customer j on event day t. All independent variables are winsorized at the

Page 109: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

94

1% and 99% percentiles and t-statistics are reported using heteroskedasticity-corrected

standard errors based on White (1980).65

Table 4.9: Cross-Sectional Cumulative Abnormal Return Regressions The sample contains all large customer abnormal return shock events, defined as customer abnormal returns three standard deviations above (positive events) or below (negative events) the mean, which can be matched with an economically-linked supplier between January 1981 and December 2004. The table shows event-time regressions of supplier CAR t[t+1,t+20], the sum of supplier raw returns minus the respec-tive equal-weighted size-quintile portfolio over the 20 post-event day window [t+1,t+20], on a constant and customer and supplier characteristics. CUSTAR is the event day customer raw return minus the CRSP value-weighted return, SUPPAR is the event day supplier raw return minus the respective equal-weighted size-quintile portfolio, SUPPSIZE is the natural logarithm of the event day supplier market capitalization, and WITHININD is a dummy taking the value of one for within-industry customer return shock events (customer and supplier are in the same industry), and 0 for across industry events (customer and supplier are in different industries). Panel A shows the results for positive events and Panel B for negative events. Specification I is the base regression, specification II adds year dummies, specification III adds industry dummies, and specification IV includes both year and industry dummies. Independent variables are winsorized at the 99 and 1% level, heteroskedasticity-corrected White t-statistics are re-ported in parentheses below the coefficient estimates, which are displayed x 100.

Panel A: Positive Events Panel B: Negative Events

Dependent Variable: Supplier CAR[t+1,t+20]

I II III IV I II III IV

CONSTANT 1.63 -0.12 0.45 -1.25 -2.50 -3.05 -4.43 -4.91(1.04) (-0.07) (0.14) (-0.38) (-1.30) (-1.24) (-0.62) (-0.67)

CUSTARt+0 3.94 2.19 2.92 0.88 2.02 5.64 4.33 7.17(1.42) (0.74) (1.03) (0.29) (0.61) (1.57) (1.25) (1.92)

SUPPARt+0 -13.63 -13.81 -14.75 -14.89 -12.27 -13.51 -12.56 -13.83(-3.12) (-3.15) (-3.36) (-3.39) (-2.52) (-2.78) (-2.57) (-2.85)

SUPPSIZE -0.07 -0.04 -0.09 -0.07 0.11 0.02 0.13 0.01(-0.86) (-0.49) (-1.07) (-0.80) (1.19) (0.21) (1.20) (0.06)

WITHININD 0.72 0.92 1.33 1.33 3.05 2.30 4.54 3.88(0.66) (0.82) (0.87) (0.86) (1.55) (1.15) (1.80) (1.52)

Year dummies No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

Industry dummies No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes

Adjusted R² (%) 0.10 0.34 0.16 0.39 0.08 0.92 0.20 1.01

F-statistic 5.06 2.98 1.49 1.81 3.29 4.68 1.43 2.47(p-value) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01) (0.00) (0.01) (0.00) (0.02) (0.00)

Degrees of freedom 15,246 15,223 15,199 15,176 10,573 10,550 10,526 10,503

65 I also experimented with a variable measuring the percentage of supplier sales going to the respective customer (see Table 4.1) to measure the importance of the customer to the supplier as in Panel A of Table 4.8. However, due to missing data for a significant number of suppliers I did not include it in the final regression.

Page 110: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

95

Given my prior findings on the changing nature of the return predictability over time

and the importance of industries, in addition to the baseline regression specification I, I

also report a specification II adding year dummies, a specification III adding (supplier)

industry dummies, and a specification IV adding both year and industry dummies. Panel

A reports the regression results for positive events and Panel B for negative events. Ad-

justed R² are relatively low across all specifications as usual in such CAR regressions,

the maximum value reached is only about 1%. All F-statistics, however, indicate overall

significance for the regression models.66

The inclusion of most of the explanatory variables is obvious given my prior

findings. First, for positive events in Panel A, the event-day customer abnormal return

has the expected positive influence on the post-event supplier CAR, albeit without sta-

tistical significance in any of the four regression specifications. Nevertheless, the coef-

ficient is consistently positive, i.e., the higher the large price change the higher the post-

event supplier drift, a result already visible in Table 4.3 comparing Panel A (three stan-

dard deviations distance) and Panel B (four standard deviations distance). A similar

conclusion can be deduced from the consistently positive coefficients in Panel B of

Table 4.9 for negative events, i.e., the more negative the large price change the more

(negative) post-event supplier drift can be observed. However, this finding is only sta-

tistically significant for specification IV.

Second, the coefficient on the event day supplier abnormal return is also consis-

tent with intuition and prior findings: it has a statistically significant negative effect in

all specifications and for both positive and negative events. This is in line with the evi-

dence reported in Table 4.4, i.e., for positive events the larger the contemporaneous

positive supplier reaction the smaller the subsequent positive post-event CAR, and for

negative events the larger the contemporaneous negative supplier reaction the smaller

the subsequent negative post-event CAR.

66 T-statistics are qualitatively unchanged if I use Newey and West (1987) autocorrelation- and het-eroskedasticity-corrected standard errors at various lags instead of the White (1980) correction.

Page 111: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

96

Third, I include the within-industry dummy in the regression. Given the evi-

dence in Table 4.5 the results are not surprising: Panel A for positive events shows a

significantly positive coefficient across all specifications while Panel B for negative

events shows no significance at all. Hence, for positive events the post-event supplier

CAR is significantly greater if supplier and customer are in the same industry, a finding

which confirms the subsample results in Table 4.5.

Fourth, I investigate the effect of supplier size. For positive events in Panel A

the coefficients are negative but not statistically significant with t-statistics around 1.

For negative events in Panel B the findings are similar as all coefficients are positive but

do not show statistical significance in any of the four specifications. Hence, according

to the regression results larger firms do show lower return predictability as reported in

Table 4.6, but this finding is not statistically reliable.

Summing up, the CAR regressions demonstrate that my findings are robust to

the consideration of all variables simultaneously and do not change after the addition of

year or industry dummies.

4.5 Conclusion

This essay suggests that the return predictability across assets demonstrated by Cohen

and Frazzini (2006) for the monthly horizon is considerably less pronounced when ex-

amined in an event study framework using daily stock returns and looking at large, at-

tention-grabbing customer price changes. I show that for large positive (negative) cus-

tomer price changes supplier stocks experience significantly positive (negative) CAR

for up to 20 days after the event. However, the major part of these returns arises in the

first five days, indicating that capital markets are relatively efficient in incorporating

extreme customer return shocks into supplier stock prices. Furthermore, I show that no

such return predictability exists for the largest firms and, in the case of negative events,

for the more recent part of the time period investigated. My findings hold both within as

well as across industries, and vary as expected with the initial supplier stock price reac-

tion, the natural proxy for limited investor attention in this setting.

Page 112: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

97

My finding of only very short-run supplier return predictability for the tails of

the customer return distribution extends the existing literature on limited investor atten-

tion. We know from the evidence in Menzly and Ozbas (2006), Cohen and Frazzini

(2006), and Hong, Torous and Valkanov (2007), among others, that there exists a wide-

spread return predictability across assets in capital markets, most likely due to limited

investor attention and capacity constraints in information processing. However, investor

attention is only ‘partially limited’ when examining large, attention-grabbing customer

price changes, as the ensuing return predictability is short-lived and confined to the first

week after the event. Hence, the return predictability from customers to suppliers un-

covered by Cohen and Frazzini (2006) does not hold completely for the tails of the cus-

tomer return distribution. This result is reassuring as a longer-lived return predictability

for these extreme events would have indicated a widespread and blatant form of market

inefficiency, given that these customer-supplier links are publicly available to all inves-

tors.

Overall, my evidence refutes only the most obvious form of limited investor at-

tention, i.e., supplier return predictability after large, attention-grabbing customer price

changes. Hence, limited investor attention may still play an important role in under-

standing asset price dynamics for less extreme cases. Future research should examine

the impact of different types of information on investor attention, e.g., by examining

supplier return predictability following large customer price changes classified by news

reports. This may allow us to gain a better understanding of information processing by

investors and the impact of limited attention on asset prices. Furthermore, future re-

search should investigate empirical evidence on limited investor attention carefully and

very closely to determine the precise extent to which any effects of limited investor at-

tention on asset prices can be observed. More detailed scrutiny is certainly warranted.

Page 113: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

99

5 Conclusion

Overall, this doctoral thesis follows the research objective to improve our understanding

of the efficiency of capital markets by providing new evidence on the information in-

corporation process at the single-firm, industry, and cross-industry level.

To achieve its research objective, this doctoral thesis comprises three essays that

conduct original empirical research using U.S. capital market data. The first two essays

both investigate the importance of M&A for stock prices. The first essay (Chapter 2)

focuses on the single-firm level and investigates the long-term performance of rival

firms directly affected by M&A transactions. Following a similar intuition, the second

essay (Chapter 3) takes an industry perspective and examines the long-term perform-

ance of industry portfolios depending on the impact of M&A on the firms in the indus-

try. Finally, the third essay (Chapter 4) focuses on the cross-industry level, as it exam-

ines explicit economic links between firms and investigates the information transmis-

sion from customer stock prices to supplier stock prices.

Although different in focus and approach, all three essays contribute to the main

challenge of developing a better understanding of a central asset pricing issue: how effi-

ciently do capital markets incorporate new information into the stock price discovery

process. Are capital markets efficient or can we empirically observe violations of mar-

ket efficiency in the information incorporation process?

In general, I find new evidence supporting the view of many researchers in be-

havioral finance that capital markets are not perfectly efficient. In the three different

essays, I document return predictability at the single-firm, industry, and cross-industry

level, which refutes the notion that the information incorporation process for related

firms is completely efficient.

My findings fit well into the results of recent research on underreaction of capi-

tal markets to new information (Frazzini (2006), Jackson and Johnson (2006), Zhang

(2006)) and the effects of limited investor attention (Hou and Moskowitz (2005), Cohen

Page 114: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

100

and Frazzini (2006), Hong, Torous and Valkanov (2007), Hou (2007)). Overall, this

doctoral thesis provides some promising avenues for future research on the information

incorporation process in capital markets.

Page 115: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

101

References

Agrawal, Anup, Jeffrey F. Jaffe, and Gershon N. Mandelker, 1992, The Post-Merger Performance of Acquiring Firms: A Re-Examination of an Anomaly, Journal of Finance 47 (4), 1605-1621.

Akhigbe, Aigbe, and Anna D. Martin, 2000, Information-Signaling and Competitive Effects of Foreign Acquisitions in the US, Journal of Banking and Finance 24 (8), 1307-1321.

Ambrose, Brent W., and William L. Megginson, 1992, The Role of Asset Structure, Ownership Structure, and Takeover Defenses in Determining Acquisition Like-lihood, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 27 (4), 575-589.

Andrade, Gregor, Mark Mitchell, and Erik Stafford, 2001, New Evidence and Perspec-tives on Mergers, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15 (2), 103-120.

Asquith, Paul, 1983, Merger Bids, Uncertainty, and Stockholder Returns, Journal of Financial Economics 11 (1-4), 51-83.

Banz, Rolf W., 1981, The Relationship between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks, Journal of Financial Economics 9 (1), 3-18.

Barber, Brad M., and John D. Lyon, 1997, Detecting Long-Run Abnormal Stock Re-turns: The Empirical Power and Specification of Test Statistics, Journal of Fi-nancial Economics 43 (3), 341-372.

Barber, Brad M., and Terrance Odean, 2006, All That Glitters: The Effect of Attention and News on the Buying Behavior of Individual and Institutional Investors, Re-view of Financial Studies, forthcoming.

Basu, Sanjoy, 1983, The Relationship between Earnings' Yield, Market Value and Re-turn for Nyse Common Stocks: Further Evidence, Journal of Financial Econom-ics 12 (1), 129-156.

Bernard, Victor L., and Jacob K. Thomas, 1989, Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: Delayed Price Response or Risk Premium?, Journal of Accounting Research 27, 1-36.

Bremer, Marc, and Richard J. Sweeney, 1991, The Reversal of Large Stock-Price De-creases, Journal of Finance 46 (2), 747-754.

Page 116: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

102

Brown, Keith C., W. V. Harlow, and Seha M. Tinic, 1988, Risk Aversion, Uncertain Information, and Market Efficiency, Journal of Financial Economics 22 (2), 355-385.

Brown, Stephen J., and Jerold B. Warner, 1980, Measuring Security Price Performance, Journal of Financial Economics 8 (3), 205-258.

Brown, Stephen J., and Jerold B. Warner, 1985, Using Daily Stock Returns: The Case of Event Studies, Journal of Financial Economics 14 (1), 3-31.

Campbell, John Y., 2000, Asset Pricing at the Millennium, Journal of Finance 55 (4), 1515-67.

Chan, Wesley S., 2003, Stock Price Reaction to News and No-News: Drift and Reversal after Headlines, Journal of Financial Economics 70 (2), 223-60.

Cohen, Laura, and Andrea Frazzini, 2006, Economic Links and Predictable Returns, Journal of Finance, forthcoming.

Cox, Don R., and David R. Peterson, 1994, Stock Returns Following Large One-Day Declines: Evidence on Short-Term Reversals and Longer-Term Performance, Journal of Finance 49 (1), 255-267.

Cremers, K. J. Martin, Vinay B. Nair, and Kose John, 2007, Takeovers and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns, Working Paper, Yale, Wharton, and Stern.

Daniel, Kent, and Sheridan Titman, 1997, Evidence on the Characteristics of Cross Sec-tional Variation in Stock Returns, Journal of Finance 52 (1), 1-33.

De Bondt, Werner F. M., and Richard Thaler, 1985, Does the Stock Market Overreact?, Journal of Finance 40 (3), 793-805.

Desai, Hemang, and Prem C. Jain, 1999, Firm Performance and Focus: Long-Run Stock Market Performance Following Spinoffs, Journal of Financial Economics 54 (1), 75-101.

Eberhart, Allan C., William F. Maxwell, and Akhtar R. Siddique, 2004, An Examina-tion of Long-Term Abnormal Stock Returns and Operating Performance Follow-ing R&D Increases, Journal of Finance 59 (2), 623-650.

Eckbo, B. Espen, 1983, Horizontal Mergers, Collusion, and Stockholder Wealth, Jour-nal of Financial Economics 11 (1-4), 241-273.

Eckbo, B. Espen, 1985, Mergers and the Market Concentration Doctrine: Evidence from the Capital Market, Journal of Business 58 (3), 325-349.

Fama, Eugene F., 1970, Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work, Journal of Finance 25 (2), 383-417.

Page 117: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

103

Fama, Eugene F., 1991, Efficient Capital Markets: II, Journal of Finance 46 (5), 1575-617.

Fama, Eugene F., 1998, Market Efficiency, Long-Term Returns, and Behavioral Fi-nance, Journal of Financial Economics 49 (3), 283-306.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1992, The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns, Journal of Finance 47 (2), 427-465.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1993, Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stock and Bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33 (1), 3-56.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1996, Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pric-ing Anomalies, Journal of Finance 51 (1), 55-84.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1997, Industry Costs of Equity, Journal of Financial Economics 43 (2), 153-193.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 2007, Dissecting Anomalies, Journal of Fi-nance, forthcoming.

Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth, 1973, Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empiri-cal Tests, Journal of Political Economy 81 (3), 607-36.

Fee, C. Edward, and Shawn Thomas, 2004, Sources of Gains in Horizontal Mergers: Evidence from Customer, Supplier, and Rival Firms, Journal of Financial Eco-nomics 74 (3), 423-460.

Frazzini, Andrea, 2006, The Disposition Effect and Underreaction to News, Journal of Finance 61 (4), 2017-2046.

Frazzini, Andrea, and Owen A. Lamont, 2006, The Earnings Announcement Premium and Trading Volume, Working Paper, University of Chicago and Yale Univer-sity.

Fuller, Kathleen, Jeffry Netter, and Mike Stegemoller, 2002, What Do Returns to Ac-quiring Firms Tell Us? Evidence from Firms That Make Many Acquisitions, Journal of Finance 57 (4), 1763-1793.

Funke, Christian, Timo Gebken, Lutz Johanning, and Volker Floegel, 2008, The Dy-namics within Merger Waves - Evidence from Industry Merger Waves of the 1990s, Working Paper, European Business School.

Gervais, Simon, Ron Kaniel, and Dan H. Mingelgrin, 2001, The High-Volume Return Premium, Journal of Finance 56 (3), 877-919.

Hasbrouck, Joel, 1985, The Characteristics of Takeover Targets: Q and Other Measures, Journal of Banking and Finance 9 (3), 351-362.

Page 118: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

104

Hirshleifer, David, 2001, Investor Psychology and Asset Pricing, Journal of Finance 56 (4), 1533-1597.

Hirshleifer, David, and Siew Hong Teoh, 2003, Limited Attention, Information Disclo-sure, and Financial Reporting, Journal of Accounting and Economics 36 (1-3), 337-386.

Hong, Harrison, Terence Lim, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2000, Bad News Travels Slowly: Size, Analyst Coverage, and the Profitability of Momentum Strategies, Journalof Finance 55 (1), 265-295.

Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1999, A Unified Theory of Underreaction, Mo-mentum Trading, and Overreaction in Asset Markets, Journal of Finance 54 (6), 2143-2184.

Hong, Harrison, Walter Torous, and Rossen Valkanov, 2007, Do Industries Lead Stock Markets?, Journal of Financial Economics 83 (2), 367-396.

Hou, Kewei, 2007, Industry Information Diffusion and the Lead-Lag Effect in Stock Returns, Review of Financial Studies 20 (4), 1113-1138.

Hou, Kewei, and Tobias J. Moskowitz, 2005, Market Frictions, Price Delay, and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns, Review of Financial Studies 18 (3), 981-1020.

Hou, Kewei, Lin Peng, and Wei Xiong, 2006, A Tale of Two Anomalies: The Implica-tion of Investor Attention for Price and Earnings Momentum, Working Paper, Ohio State University, Baruch College, and Princeton University.

Huberman, Gur, and Tomer Regev, 2001, Contagious Speculation and a Cure for Can-cer: A Nonevent That Made Stock Prices Soar, Journal of Finance 56 (1), 387-396.

Ikenberry, David L., Graeme Rankine, and Earl K. Stice, 1996, What Do Stock Splits Really Signal?, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31 (3), 357-375.

Ikenberry, David, Josef Lakonishok, and Theo Vermaelen, 1995, Market Underreaction to Open Market Share Repurchases, Journal of Financial Economics 39 (2-3), 181-208.

Jackson, Andrew, and Timothy Johnson, 2006, Unifying Underreaction Anomalies, Journal of Business 79 (1), 75-114.

Jaffe, Jeffrey F., 1974, Special Information and Insider Trading, Journal of Business 47 (3), 410-428.

Page 119: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

105

Jarrell, Gregg A., James A. Brickley, and Jeffry M. Netter, 1988, The Market for Cor-porate Control: The Empirical Evidence since 1980, Journal of Economic Per-spectives 2 (1), 49-68.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, 1990, Evidence of Predictable Behavior of Security Returns, Journal of Finance 45 (3), 881-898.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Jason Karceski, 2004, Long-Run Performance Evaluation: Correlation and Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Tests, Working Paper, Emory University and University of Florida.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 1993, Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance 48 (1), 65-91.

Jensen, Michael C., and Richard S. Ruback, 1983, The Market for Corporate Control: The Scientific Evidence, Journal of Financial Economics 11 (1-4), 5-50.

Kahneman, Daniel, 1973. Attention and Effort (Experimental Psychology), Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs (NJ).

Kothari, S. P., and Jerold B. Warner, 1997, Measuring Long-Horizon Security Price Performance, Journal of Financial Economics 43 (3), 301-339.

Kothari, S. P., and Jerold B. Warner, 2007, Econometrics of Event Studies, in B. Espen Eckbo, ed.: Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance, El-sevier/North Holland, Amsterdam/Oxford.

Lee, Charles M. C., and Bhaskaran Swaminathan, 2000, Price Momentum and Trading Volume, Journal of Finance 55 (5), 2017-69.

Lintner, John, 1965, The Valuation of Risky Assets and the Selection of Risky Invest-ments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets, Review of Economics and Statis-tics 47 (1), 13-37.

Lo, Andrew W., and A. Craig MacKinlay, 1990, When Are Contrarian Profits Due to Stock Market Overreaction?, Review of Financial Studies 3 (2), 175-205.

Loderer, Claudio, and Kenneth Martin, 1992, Postacquisition Performance of Acquiring Firms, Financial Management 21 (3), 69-79.

Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter, 1995, The New Issues Puzzle, Journal of Finance 50 (1), 23-51.

Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter, 2000, Uniformly Least Powerful Tests of Market Ef-ficiency, Journal of Financial Economics 55 (3), 361-389.

Page 120: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

106

Loughran, Tim, and Anand M. Vijh, 1997, Do Long-Term Shareholders Benefit from Corporate Acquisitions?, Journal of Finance 52 (5), 1765-1790.

Lyon, John D., Brad M. Barber, and Chih-Ling Tsai, 1999, Improved Methods for Tests of Long-Run Abnormal Stock Returns, Journal of Finance 54 (1), 165-201.

Mandelker, Gershon, 1974, Risk and Return: The Case of Merging Firms, Journal of Financial Economics 1 (4), 303-335.

Massa, Massimo, Zahid Rehman, and Theo Vermaelen, 2007, Mimicking Repurchases, Journal of Financial Economics 84 (3), 624-666.

Masulis, Ronald W., Cong Wang, and Fei Xie, 2007, Corporate Governance and Ac-quirer Returns, Journal of Finance 62 (4), 1851-1889.

Menzly, Lior, and Oguzhan Ozbas, 2006, Cross-Industry Momentum, Working Paper, Vega Asset Management and University of Southern California.

Merton, Robert C., 1973, An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model, Econometrica 41 (5), 867-887.

Merton, Robert C., 1987, A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incom-plete Information, Journal of Finance 42 (3), 483-510.

Michaely, Roni, Richard H. Thaler, and Kent L. Womack, 1995, Price Reactions to Dividend Initiations and Omissions: Overreaction or Drift?, Journal of Finance50 (2), 573-608.

Mitchell, Mark L., and Erik Stafford, 2000, Managerial Decisions and Long-Term Stock Price Performance, Journal of Business 73 (3), 287-329.

Mitchell, Mark, Todd Pulvino, and Erik Stafford, 2004, Price Pressure around Mergers, Journal of Finance 59 (1), 31-63.

Moeller, Sara B., Frederik P. Schlingemann, and Rene M. Stulz, 2004, Firm Size and the Gains from Acquisitions, Journal of Financial Economics 73 (2), 201-228.

Moeller, Sara B., Frederik P. Schlingemann, and Rene M. Stulz, 2007, How Do Diver-sity of Opinion and Information Asymmetry Affect Acquirer Returns?, Review of Financial Studies 20 (5), 2048-2078.

Moskowitz, Tobias J., and Mark Grinblatt, 1999, Do Industries Explain Momentum?, Journal of Finance 54 (4), 1249-1290.

Mossin, Jan, 1966, Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market, Econometrica 34 (4), 768-783.

Page 121: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

107

Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West, 1987, A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix, Econo-metrica 55 (3), 703-708.

Nisbett, Richard E., and Lee Ross, 1980. Human Inference: Strategies and Shortcom-ings of Social Judgement, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs (NJ).

Park, Jinwoo, 1995, A Market Microstructure Explanation for Predictable Variations in Stock Returns Following Large Price Changes, Journal of Financial and Quan-titative Analysis 30 (2), 241-256.

Pashler, Harold E., 1998. Attention, Psychology Press, Philadelphia (PA).

Peng, Lin, 2005, Learning with Information Capacity Constraints, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 40 (2), 307-329.

Peng, Lin, and Wei Xiong, 2006, Investor Attention, Overconfidence and Category Learning, Journal of Financial Economics 80 (3), 563-602.

Pritamani, Mahesh, and Vijay Singal, 2001, Return Predictability Following Large Price Changes and Information Releases, Journal of Banking and Finance 25 (4), 631-656.

Purnanandam, Amiyatosh K., and Bhaskaran Swaminathan, 2004, Are Ipos Really Un-derpriced?, Review of Financial Studies 17 (3), 811-848.

Rau, P. Raghavendra, and Theo Vermaelen, 1998, Glamour, Value and the Post-Acquisition Performance of Acquiring Firms, Journal of Financial Economics49 (2), 223-253.

Rosenberg, Barr, Kenneth Reid, and Ronald Lanstein, 1985, Persuasive Evidence of Market Inefficiency, Journal of Portfolio Management 11 (3), 9-16.

Ross, Stephen A., 1976, The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing, Journal of Economic Theory 13 (3), 341-360.

Shahrur, Husayn, 2005, Industry Structure and Horizontal Takeovers: Analysis of Wealth Effects on Rivals, Suppliers, and Corporate Customers, Journal of Fi-nancial Economics 76 (1), 61-98.

Sharpe, William, 1964, Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk, Journal of Finance 19 (3), 425-442.

Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny, 1997, The Limits of Arbitrage, The Journal of Finance 52 (1), 35-55.

Page 122: Selected essay in empirical asset pricing

108

Song, Moon H., and Ralph A. Walkling, 2000, Abnormal Returns to Rivals of Acquisi-tion Targets: A Test of the 'Acquisition Probability Hypothesis.', Journal of Fi-nancial Economics 55 (2), 143-171.

Spiess, D. Katherine, and John Affleck-Graves, 1995, Underperformance in Long-Run Stock Returns Following Seasoned Equity Offerings, Journal of Financial Eco-nomics 38 (3), 243-267.

Spiess, D. Katherine, and John Affleck-Graves, 1999, The Long-Run Performance of Stock Returns Following Debt Offerings, Journal of Financial Economics 54 (1), 45-73.

Stulz, Rene M., 1990, Managerial Discretion and Optimal Financing Policies, Journal of Financial Economics 26 (1), 3-27.

White, Halbert, 1980, A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity, Econometrica 48 (4), 817-838.

Zhang, X. Frank, 2006, Information Uncertainty and Stock Returns, Journal of Finance61 (1), 105-136.