The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that...

28
econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW – Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW – Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. Terms of use: Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your personal and scholarly purposes. You are not to copy documents for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. If the documents have been made available under an Open Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. zbw Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Mavromaras, Kostas; McGuinness, Seamus; Fok, Yin King Working Paper Overskilling dynamics and education pathways ESRI working paper, No. 307 Provided in Cooperation with: The Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI), Dublin Suggested Citation: Mavromaras, Kostas; McGuinness, Seamus; Fok, Yin King (2009) : Overskilling dynamics and education pathways, ESRI working paper, No. 307 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/50143

Transcript of The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that...

Page 1: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

econstor www.econstor.eu

Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW – Leibniz-Informationszentrum WirtschaftThe Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW – Leibniz Information Centre for Economics

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichenZwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielleZwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglichmachen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.

Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dortgenannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.

Terms of use:

Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for yourpersonal and scholarly purposes.

You are not to copy documents for public or commercialpurposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make thempublicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwiseuse the documents in public.

If the documents have been made available under an OpenContent Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), youmay exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicatedlicence.

zbw Leibniz-Informationszentrum WirtschaftLeibniz Information Centre for Economics

Mavromaras, Kostas; McGuinness, Seamus; Fok, Yin King

Working Paper

Overskilling dynamics and education pathways

ESRI working paper, No. 307

Provided in Cooperation with:The Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI), Dublin

Suggested Citation: Mavromaras, Kostas; McGuinness, Seamus; Fok, Yin King (2009) :Overskilling dynamics and education pathways, ESRI working paper, No. 307

This Version is available at:http://hdl.handle.net/10419/50143

Page 2: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

www.esri.ie

Working Paper No. 307

July 2009

Overskilling Dynamics and Education Pathways*

Kostas Mavromaras1, 3, Seamus McGuinness2, Yin King Fok1

Abstract: This paper uses panel data and econometric methods to estimate the incidence and the dynamic properties of overskilling among employed individuals. The paper begins by asking whether there is extensive overskilling in the labour market, and whether overskilling differs by education pathway. The answer to both questions is yes. The paper continues by asking whether overskilling is a self-perpetuating labour market state (state dependence), and whether state dependence differs by education pathway. The paper uses a dynamic random effects probit which includes Mundlak corrections and it models the initial conditions following Heckman’s method. It finds that there is extensive overskilling state dependence in the workplace, and to the degree that overskilling can be interpreted as skills underutilisation and worker-job mismatch, this is an important finding. Overskilled workers with a higher degree show the highest state dependence, while workers with vocational education show none. Workers with no post-school qualifications are somewhere between these two groups. The finding that higher degree graduates suffer the greatest overskilling state dependence, combined with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, offers an additional useful perspective to compare the attributes of vocational and degree qualifications. Keywords: Overskilling, education pathways, state dependence, dynamic estimation. Correspondence Author: [email protected]. *Mavromaras and McGuinness jointly assume the first authorship of this paper. The data used is the confidentialised unit record file from the Household, Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia (HILDA) survey. The HILDA Survey Project was initiated, and is funded, by the Australian Government Department of Families, Housing, Community Services and Indigenous Affairs, and is managed by the Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research. The authors are grateful to the National Centre for Vocational Education Research (NCVER) for financial support. The usual disclaimer applies. 1Melbourne Institute, University of Melbourne 2Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin 3IZA, Bonn

ESRI working papers represent un-refereed work-in-progress by members who are solely responsible for the content and any views expressed therein. Any comments on these papers will be welcome and should be sent to the author(s) by email. Papers may be downloaded for personal use only.

Page 3: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Overskilling Dynamics and Education Pathways 1. Introduction This paper examines the dynamic properties of overskilling and its relationship with the

level of qualifications of overskilled workers. Overskilling is defined as the situation

where an employed worker reports that their skills are not fully utilised in their job. It is

taken to reflect a form of skills underutilisation in the workplace, and the possibility of a

mismatch between the worker and the job. Overskilling has been emerging as a key

measure of mismatch in recent literature, in preference to the more commonly used

overeducation variable (see Sloane 2003; McGuinness 2006; O’Leary et al. 2009 for

overviews of this literature). One of the arguments put forward is that overskilling is a

more general, and potentially more robust, measure of skills under-utilisation in the

labour market than is overeducation (O’Leary et al. 2009). A well-documented adverse

outcome resulting from overskilling is lower earnings, especially for university graduates.

Overskilled workers use a smaller proportion of their skills. As a result they are less

productive and command lower wages than their well-matched counterparts (see Green &

Zhu 2008; Mavromaras et al. 2009).

This paper examines a novel aspect of overskilling, namely its dynamic properties and

the possible presence of state dependence of overskilling. State dependence is defined as

the degree to which the effect of any initial endowments (often referred to as individual

heterogeneity, or simply characteristics) on an outcome may be attenuated or accentuated

by the continued presence of that outcome (Lancaster 1979; Heckman 1981; 1991). State

dependence is distinct from heterogeneity, and this distinction must be explicitly

modelled in estimation for the correct understanding of outcomes that persist over time.

This paper follows Heckman’s (1981) method. The presence of state dependence in

overskilling is important for policy reasons, as the cost of labour market mismatches for

individuals depends on both the size of the wage penalty and on how long that penalty

persists. A number of theories suggest that labour market mismatches are temporary (see

Sloane et al. 1999). In matching theories of job search (Jovanovic 1979), mismatched

workers improve job matches through repeated job search. Theories of career mobility

2

Page 4: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

(Rosen 1972; Sicherman & Galor 1990) predict that workers may deliberately enter their

preferred profession at a level lower than is commensurate with their qualifications. This

enables them to acquire further skills, through on-the-job training and learning, and

promotes a more rapid career progression. Both theories could explain overskilling as a

temporary phenomenon, but the presence of state dependence where being presently

overskilled may influence the chances of continued overskilling could cast doubt on these

predictions. Although these theoretical issues have been recognised in many instances,

the empirical aspects of persistent mismatch have not received adequate attention in the

literature, principally due to the lack of appropriate longitudinal data on overskilling.

The paper distinguishes employees by their highest educational attainment and considers

the extent to which overskilling may differ by education level. The underlying theoretical

motivation for this distinction draws on the potential differences in the way general and

specific human capital can be utilised in the workplace. In particular, we examine

overskilling differences between individuals who undertook specific vocational education

and training, and those who obtained their qualifications via a more general academic

education pathway. We build on our knowledge that overskilling varies by education

pathway (Mavromaras et al 2009) and examine the possibility that state dependence may

differ by education type and level. The outcome of this investigation will improve our

understanding of the relative merits of rebalancing the current mix of vocational versus

academic educational provision.

This paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the pertinent aspects of the

Household Income and Labour Dynamics in Australia (HILDA) survey longitudinal data,

which contains individuals’ information on overskilling and education. Section 3 explains

the econometric method we use for the estimation of overskilling state dependence.

Section 4 presents and discusses the estimation results. Section 5 concludes. An

Appendix contains full descriptive statistics and estimation results.

2. The data The data for this paper come from the first six waves of the HILDA survey. HILDA is a

nationally representative panel dataset of the Australian population that has been

3

Page 5: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

collected annually since 2001. The sample used here begins with the unbalanced panel of

working-age employees (15-64 years for male; 15-59 for female) and contains a total of

42,255 person-year observations. The overskilling variable is constructed using the 7-

point scale responses to the following question: “I use many of my skills and abilities in

my current job”. A response of 1 corresponds with strongly disagree and 7 with strongly

agree. The question is similar to that used in both the work of Allen & van der Velden

(2001) and Green & McIntosh (2002).1 All respondents in the sample were classified into

one of three groups for each yearly observation: (i) the severely overskilled (selecting 1,

2, or 3 on the scale); (ii) the moderately overskilled (selecting 4 or 5); and (iii) the well-

matched (selecting 6 or 7). Sensitivity tests confirm that the cut-off points for severe and

moderate overskilling are appropriate (Mavromaras et al. 2009).2

Table 1: Reported Overskilling in Paid Employment Extent of Overskilling (%) Highest Education Level

(Australia) Well Matched

Moderately Overskilled

Severely Overskilled

%

Year 10 and below 50.99 30.68 18.32 18.69 Year 11-12 47.39 32.25 20.36 25.79 Certificates I and II and below 45.19 35.88 18.92 1.73 Certificates III and IV and apprenticeship 62.13 27.88 9.99 21.02 Advanced diploma and tertiary 62.46 26.33 11.21 32.78 All qualifications 56.06 29.16 14.78 100.00 No of observations 23,688 12,322 6,245 42,255

Note: HILDA Waves 1 to 6 (years 2001-2006) were used with population weights

1 In the data employed by Allen & van der Velden (2001), a measure of skills underutilisation is constructed from responses, scored on a 5-point scale, to the statement: “My current job offers me sufficient scope to use my knowledge and skills”. In contrast, Green and McIntosh (2002) combine responses to two items, both of which have four possible response options. These items are: “In my current job I have enough opportunity to use the knowledge and skills that I have”; and “How much of your past experience, skills and abilities can you make use of in your present job?” 2 A question arises in this context, namely whether in responding to the overskilling question, employees are not consistently factoring in skills that have no relevance to their current job. McGuinness & Wooden (2009) cross-tabulated the overskilling variable with a measure of job complexity to confirm that the more overskilled the worker, the less difficult they consider their job. They argue that this association demonstrates that the overskilling responses will not be biased by respondents having incorporated non-labour-market-relevant skills and abilities into these responses. Job complexity is assessed using responses to the item “My job is complex or difficult”, which is scored on the same 7-point scale used to measure overskilling.

4

Page 6: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

We group education by the highest educational qualification obtained: below year 11 (no

qualifications), year 11 or 12 (accredited qualifications at compulsory schooling level),

certificates (vocational), diplomas and other higher degrees. We sub-divide the

vocational education category of certificates into (a) Certificates I and II and below and

(b) Certificates III and IV and apprenticeships. Table 1 reports the incidence of

overskilling for all employees by education level and shows high incidence and

differences by education level.

An interesting observation is the high proportion of workers with few qualifications

reporting themselves underutilised in the workplace (around 20 percent severely

overskilled and 30 percent moderately) and the high proportion of workers with post-

compulsory school qualifications reporting themselves well-matched (above 60 percent).

This finding may relate to a high incidence of jobs requiring only very basic skills in the

Australian labour market which, may, in turn, relate to its sectoral composition.

3 Estimation method This paper utilises the panel nature of the HILDA data to estimate the dynamics of

overskilling. We estimate the following equation:

(1) itiititit uOSXOS +++= − εγβ 1'

for i=1,…,N, individuals observed over t=2,…,T periods. OSit is the overskilling variable

which takes the value 1 for those who are overskilled and 0 for those who are well-

matched, Xit contains all observed explanatory variables and εi and uit are components of

the error term with uit assumed to be iid. However, two subtle but nonetheless serious

estimation problems would arise if Equation 1 were to be estimated using a standard

random effects framework. The first problem stems from the assumption of independence

between the error terms and the covariates in the random effects model, and the second

problem stems from the inclusion of a lagged dependent variable in the right-hand side of

Equation 1 and its correlation with the error terms.

The problems arising from the unrealistic assumption of independence between the

covariates and the error term can be resolved within the random effects framework

through the application of Mundlak (1978) corrections. This is done by assuming that the

relationship between Xit and εi can be written as iii vX += εε ' , where follows the iidvi ~

5

Page 7: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

normal distribution and is independent of Xit and uit for all i and t. In practice this

correction amounts to including in the right-hand side of Equation 1 the individual (over

time) means for each of the time-varying explanatory variables. The time-invariance of

the individual specific error term εi. implies that even after we have corrected for its

possible correlation with observed contemporaneous factors (the Xit), εI will still be

correlated with the lagged dependent variable. It can be shown that assuming that OSit-1

and εI are independent amounts to assuming that the first observation of OSi1 is

independent of the individual-specific error term εi. This assumption is difficult to justify

on empirical or theoretical grounds. The problem was first examined in detail in the

econometrics literature by Heckman (1981); it has been named the problem of initial

conditions. Ignoring initial conditions that are correlated with the individual-specific

error term εi results in overestimating state dependence. That is, the estimated coefficient

of OSit-1 in Equation 1 will be larger than the true value of state dependence. Heckman

proposed that initial conditions be modelled by using the values of the first wave of a

panel dataset to approximate the true values of the initial conditions. It is desirable when

this method is applied, that some data that contain information that was finalised some

time before the first observed period be included as a means of identification. This

method is widely accepted in econometrics for its proven robustness and relative

simplicity in estimation. The estimations that follow incorporate both the Mundlak

corrections and Heckman’s method of accounting for the initial conditions. Equation 1

can be re-written as:

(2) itiiititit uXOSXOS ++++= − εαγβ '1

' And it has to be estimated simultaneously with the initial condition equation which is

written as:

(3) 1'11 iiii uZOS ++= θαβ

Note that Equation 2 utilises data starting from period 2 to the end of the observation

frame, while Equation 3 utilises data exclusively from period 1. Further, Zi1, the list of

right-hand side variables in Equation 3, contains all of the Xit and iX plus some

additional instruments that are chosen to contain pre-period 1 information. To this

purpose the paper uses a number of questions that were asked at the first interview to

collect individual background, historical, information. These are (i) a set of dummies

6

Page 8: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

which indicate the country of birth of the individual (Australia; not Australia but English

speaking; not Australia; and not English speaking), as the country of birth will have been

determined before overskilling status; and (ii) two further dummies indicating parental

employment status (one for a professional father, and one for a professional mother), the

values of which were also, in all probability, determined before the individual’s

overskilling status in the first period. After experimentation, and considering previous

results in the literature, we also decided to exclude the moderately overskilled from the

analysis. This amounts to having restricted our sample to estimate the sharp contrast

between the severely overskilled and the well-matched.3 Estimations were carried out

using the STATA procedure redprob developed by Stewart.4 4. Estimation results and discussion 4.1 Overskilling and state dependence Estimating a random effects dynamic panel model that controls for both initial conditions

and applied Mundlak corrections as in Equations (2) and (3) reveals the extent of

overskilling state dependence. Table 2 contains a number of specifications that support

two central findings. First, even after the application of a number of econometric

corrections that are known to remove spurious state dependence (principally by removing

heterogeneity that could contaminate the lagged dependent variable in the right-hand side

of Equation 2), there remains considerable true state dependence of overskilling. Table 2

shows that the first lag of overskilling is highly significant statistically, which

demonstrates that severe overskilling is a self-perpetuating state. The coefficient of

3 There is no evidence that moderately overskilled individuals incur significant wage penalties (Mavromaras et al 2009), or that they experience significant adverse mobility (McGuinness & Wooden 2007). Accepting this evidence we focus on the comparison between severely overskilled and well-matched workers. Thus our estimations exclude those who have been classified as moderately overskilled. 4 The STATA ado files and a number of useful related papers can be found by visiting Stewart’s website at http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/economics/staff/faculty/stewart/publications. These are well explained and are an excellent starting point for the researcher who wishes to use these estimation methods. The precise algebra of the likelihood function we estimate is presented by Stewart; we do not replicate it here.

7

Page 9: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

lagged overskilling is robust to the different specifications, as one would wish it to be.

The intuition behind this finding is that the negative effect of those characteristics that

were responsible for becoming overskilled in the first instance will be accentuated

through the experience of continued overskilling, thus strengthening the labour market

disadvantage associated with overskilling—such as lower wages.

Table 2: Dynamic Random Effects Probit Estimations for Severe Overskilling

Variable Coefficient (std. error)

Coefficient (std. error)

Coefficient (std. error)

Coefficient (std. error)

Overskilling at t-1 .78 (0.08) 0.81 (0.08) 0.84 (0.08) 0.77 (0.08) Certificates III or IV -0.28 (0.32) -0.30 (0.31) -0.30 (0.32) -0.15 (0.32) Higher degrees -1.45 (0.43) -1.23 (0.38) -1.23 (0.37) -1.10 (0.41) Gender (female=1) 0.17 (0.08) 0.07 (0.07) 0.07 (0.07) -0.24 (0.09) Occupational tenure - 0.01 (0.005) 0.003 (0.12) - Occupational tenure sq. - - 0.01 (0.035) - Hours worked - - - -0.01(0.004) Means over time Certificates III or IV -0.20 (0.34) -0.18 (0.34) -0.16 (0.34) -0.25 (0.34) Higher degrees 0.62 (0.43) 0.49 (0.39) 0.50 (0.38) 0.36 (0.42) Occupational tenure - -0.06 (0.008) -0.08 (0.13) - Occupational tenure - - 0.83 (0.33) - Hours worked - - - -0.03 (0.006)Constant -1.91 (0.09) -1.25 (0.09) -1.12 (0.097) -0.27 (0.16) ρ1 0.72 (0.02) 0.67 (0.03) 0.65 (0.26) 0.70 (0.024) θ2 0.83 (0.08) 0.93 (0.11) 0.95 (0.11) 0.88 (0.09) Log likelihood -4130.72 -4023.22 -4016.17 -4019.35 Sample size 24057 Notes: 1 ρ is an estimate of the cross-period correlation of the composite error term

iti u+ε . 2 θ is the statistic used to test whether the initial conditions are exogenous. A clearly positive value of θ rejects the hypothesis that the initial conditions are exogenous, thus lending support for adopting Heckman’s method. This result would tend to weaken the temporary mismatches predictions of matching

theory. If overskilling mismatches were simply due to asymmetric information, one

would expect that overskilled workers would have achieved more suitable matches within

a year. This result does not agree with theories of job mobility either, as it may not be as

likely that individuals seeking core experience would require a period longer than one

year to grasp the basic elements of their chosen occupation and thus cease to report

8

Page 10: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

themselves as overskilled. Experimentation with two lags of the overskilling dependent

variable indicated that overskilling state dependence remains significant for two and

perhaps three periods, but the sample sizes were reduced too much to make these results

statistically trustworthy. A longer HILDA panel will allow us to confirm this finding in

the future.

Estimation results in Table 2 may appear to be at odds with previous research that was

based largely on pooled or single cross-section data. In contrast with Mavromaras et al.

(2009) where both vocational and degree-level educational variables were significant in

an overskilling incidence equation, this paper finds that the effect of education level,

entered in the right-hand side in the form of a set of dummies that reflect completion of a

qualification between the previous and the present interviews, becomes statistically

insignificant for vocational education. It remains significant for degree-level education

(reference category ‘no post-school education’). Careful comparison confirms intuition

and suggests that the pooled estimation results in Mavromaras et al. (2009) and the panel

results in this paper are not contradictory, as they are answering two different questions.

The difference is informative. The estimates of Mavromaras et al. (2009), based on cross-

section data, reflect the difference in overskilling between people with and people

without a particular type of qualification, all observed at the same point in time. They

suggest clearly that in the long run, education pathways that lead to either vocational or

degree-level qualifications are associated with lower levels of overskilling. (Note that in

the cross-section context a qualification may have been completed at any time in the

past.) By contrast, the estimates in this paper reflect the effect that the completion of a

qualification has had on the difference in the overskilling status that was reported in the

last interview before completion, and the overskilling status reported in the first interview

after the completion of the education course in question, controlling for unobserved

individual heterogeneity. Our results suggest that those who obtain a degree qualification

report an immediate reduction in their overskilling in the first interview after completion

of their degree, while those who obtain a vocational qualification do not report such a

clear-cut reduction in their overskilling right after they have completed their vocational

qualification. The fact that the conditional associations between overskilling and

vocational education and overskilling and degree-level education are both negative, and

9

Page 11: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

of a similar magnitude (in the pooled cross-section estimations of Mavromaras et al.

2009) would lead to the suggestion that the effect of vocational education on overskilling

takes longer to emerge. This difference is not surprising when one considers the strong

and often immediate effect that obtaining a higher degree has on a graduate’s

employment opportunities. This is especially so with low-skill work that often supports

students during their study for degrees (although the data exclude full-time students).

Results suggest that the same immediate effect is not present in the case of completing a

vocational educational qualification. This section established that overskilling incidence

differs by education level, and that overskilling state dependence is clearly present. It has

also provided some indications that overskilling incidence by education level may be

different in the short run suggesting that there may be differences in the dynamics of

overskilling by education level. Therefore in next section we ask the question of whether

overskilling state dependence may be different by education level.

4.2 Does overskilling state dependence vary by education level? To answer the question of whether overskilling state dependence may be different by

education level we carried out the same estimation on three separate sub-samples by

highest education qualification at the time of interview. One sub-sample contains only

school graduates, one contains only vocational education graduates, and one contains

only higher degree graduates. The objective is to compare the direction and level of the

lagged dependent variable as a reflection of differences in state dependence by education

level. Apart from dropping the education variables from the right-hand side, the

estimation is the same as in Table 2. Table 3 below reports the results, concentrating on

the coefficients of the lagged overskilling variable.

It is clear that overskilling state persistence varies by level of education. The coefficient

on lagged overskilling for vocational education graduates is the lowest amongst all

education groups and is not significantly different to zero. This implies that vocational

education graduates who are presently overskilled are clearly no more likely to be

overskilled in the future than their presently well-matched vocational education

counterparts. This means that here we find no evidence of state dependence within the

vocational labour market.

10

Page 12: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Table 3: Dynamic RE Probit Estimations of Severe Overskilling by Education

All School Including Year

12

Certificates III and IV Higher Degrees

Overskilling at t-1

0.63*** (0.13)

0.31 (0.75)

1.11*** (0.17)

Observations 9607 5205 9245 Restricted Log Likelihood -1883.94 -828.62 -1091.84 Unrestricted Log Likelihood -1781.01 -733.23 -984.19 ρ1 0.704 (0.044) 0.72 (0.25) 0.565 (0.064) θ2 0.789 (0.130) 1.91 (3.16) 1.818 (0.584) Notes: 1 ρ is an estimate of the cross-period correlation of the composite error term

iti u+ε . 2 θ is the statistic used to test if the initial conditions are exogenous. A clearly positive value of θ rejects the hypothesis that the initial conditions are exogenous, thus lending support to the adoption of the Heckman method. A large number of control variables were included in the estimation: gender, immigration status, age, family status and number of children, employer size and sector. The estimation of the Certificates III and IV category was difficult to converge, but then it did produce sensible results. By contrast, there appears to be overskilling state dependence for both school graduates

and for higher degree graduates. The significant coefficients in the lagged overskilling

variable in Table 3 for these two educational outcomes suggests that graduates with

higher degrees who are presently overskilled in their job are more likely to find

themselves overskilled in the future than are their presently well-matched counterparts.

The same applies, but not as strongly, to overskilled school graduates. The evidence

supports the view that in the case of vocational education graduates, overskilling is more

likely to be a short-term phenomenon that dissipates (relatively) quickly enough not to be

present a year later at the next HILDA interview. The picture that emerges is one where

vocational education graduates do not realise the benefits of lower overskilling straight

after graduation (hence the incidence coefficients in Table 2 are not significant for

vocational education), but they do so in later years. Indeed, the pooled regression results

in Mavromaras et al. (2009) suggest that in the long run vocational education graduates

end up with the lowest overskilling rates in the entire labour force. By contrast, degree-

level graduates are, on average, more likely to realise the reduction of overskilling shortly

11

Page 13: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

after their graduation. However, for those who are unlucky enough to be the outliers and

who remain overskilled after graduation, the chances of escaping overskilling are reduced

through the greatest state dependence in the whole labour force.

4.3 Discussion It is worth remembering at this point a well-established result in the literature: the wage

penalties from overskilling are the lowest in the labour force for vocational graduates and

are the highest for higher degree graduates. A complex picture arises from looking jointly

at the incidence and state dependence findings presented in this paper and the wage

penalty findings. First, overskilling is less likely for vocational education and for degree-

level graduates than for school graduates (Mavromaras et al, 2009). In other words, post-

school education in general reduces the chances of overskilling. Second, the

consequences of overskilling are nowhere near as serious a problem for vocational

education graduates as they are for higher degree graduates. Overskilled vocational

education graduates suffer a much lower overskilling wage penalty (Mavromaras et al,

2009) and they have a higher probability of escaping overskilling if they have been

unlucky enough to be overskilled.5 By contrast, overskilled higher degree graduates

suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty and have the lowest probability of escaping

overskilling if they have been unlucky enough to be overskilled. School graduates appear

to be somewhere in the middle between the two post-compulsory education pathways.

A number of theoretical explanations relate to the differences in overskilling state

persistence between vocational education and higher degree graduates, but this paper

only provides some speculative suggestions. One difference between the type of

education and skills provided by schools and universities on the one hand, and vocational

education institutions on the other is the degree of sectoral and occupational specificity.

5 Mavromaras et al (2009) find considerable overskilling wage penalty using a number of econometric methodologies and the HILDA data. They distinguish their sample by the level of the highest qualification of workers and report overskilling wage penalty estimates that range from 6.3 to 7.3 percent for workers with vocational education and training to 13.7 to 19 percent for workers with higher degrees. Workers without post-school qualifications are somewhere in the middle, depending on whether they completed school or not.

12

Page 14: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

School knowledge is very general and transferable between sectors and occupations. The

same applies to a large component of university education (in terms of developing

analytical and related skills), but not to all of it. Although some degrees may be intensely

occupation-specific (for example medicine, law, accounting, and others) a very large

proportion of study for most degrees develops rather general analytical skills that can be

utilised in a wide range of occupations and sectors. By contrast, vocational education

graduates have a bigger proportion of their skills taught with a specific occupation in

mind. In terms of providing a possible explanation for lower levels of persistence in

vocational labour markets, the distinction between general and specific human capital,

and the expectations and signals associated with each type of educational pathway are

pertinent considerations. Results in this paper suggest that being overskilled and in

possession of general human capital can be a problem for the worker in terms of lower

wages and higher state persistence, especially for those workers with higher levels of

general human capital. By contrast, being overskilled and in possession of the specific

human capital developed by vocational education does not appear to be much of a

problem either in terms of lost wages or in terms of state dependence. The intuition is that

while employers are more likely to expect that workers with general human capital

should be better able to adapt to the specific needs of their job, they may be less attractive

than workers who have already developed a set of work relevant skills through vocational

education and training This type of information cannot be found in the conventional,

large datasets typically used for the analysis of workplace mismatch. A combination of

qualitative and quantitative data would be most appropriate for generating this valuable

information.

5. Summary and conclusion This paper was motivated by the growing evidence in the empirical labour economics

literature that overskilling is an important labour market phenomenon, and by the

emergence of the HILDA dataset that provides up to date panel information on

overskilling. Research to date, including that of the authors of this paper, has

concentrated primarily on the wage penalty that overskilled workers are faced with when

compared with their well-matched counterparts. This paper adds a new dimension to the

13

Page 15: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

debate by estimating the factors that are associated with the incidence and with the state

dependence of overskilling, and by showing that using dynamic panel econometric

methods makes a difference. Our findings suggest that overskilling incidence differs by

educational pathway among other factors. These findings also suggest that overskilling,

like other adverse labour market outcomes, exhibits considerable state dependence and

that this overskilling state dependence differs strongly by education pathway.

Overskilling state dependence is shown to be at its worst for higher degree graduates,

lower but still present for school graduates with no post-compulsory school education,

and not present for vocational training graduates. The paper combined these novel

findings on overskilling incidence and state dependence with existing evidence on

overskilling wage penalties to suggest that workers who complete vocational education

and training suffer the least damage by the various outcomes of overskilling in the labour

market.

14

Page 16: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Appendix Table A1: Extended results on Table 3 estimations

All schooling ( incl. Year 12)

Certificates III & IV

Higher degrees

Coeff. Std.Error Coeff. Std.Error Coeff. Std.ErrorMain panel estimation results Overskilling at t-1 0.63 0.13 0.31 0.75 1.11 0.17 Female -0.04 0.16 -0.13 0.24 -0.05 0.15 Occupational tenure 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.01 Hours worked -0.01 0.01 0.00 0.02 -0.01 0.01 Firm size up to 4 -0.10 0.28 -0.02 0.48 0.05 0.32 Firm size 5 to 9 -0.08 0.27 0.22 0.56 -0.13 0.34 Firm size 10 to 19 -0.38 0.26 0.35 0.44 -0.42 0.30 Firm size 20 to 49 -0.27 0.21 0.12 0.39 0.14 0.23 Sector Agriculture -0.88 0.68 2.36 1.19 0.19 0.78 Mining -1.91 1.17 0.28 1.12 3.02 1.04 Electricity -1.82 1.27 -0.71 2.09 0.70 1.31 Construction -0.87 0.47 1.30 1.00 0.66 0.66 Wholesale 0.81 0.40 -0.09 0.63 0.34 0.50 Retail 0.36 0.36 0.55 0.59 1.13 0.50 Accommodation 0.27 0.49 -0.54 1.29 1.30 0.91 Transport 0.16 0.46 -0.62 0.82 0.61 0.70 Commerce 0.80 0.78 1.18 1.16 1.95 1.49 Finance 0.28 0.62 -0.79 2.09 0.18 0.86 Property -0.27 0.39 0.69 0.65 -0.17 0.46 Defence -0.17 0.55 1.19 1.29 0.13 0.58 Education -0.75 0.64 2.44 1.45 0.59 0.56 Health -0.60 0.49 0.53 0.89 0.17 0.55 Cultural -0.83 0.62 -0.74 1.73 0.63 0.77 Personal -1.83 0.73 0.19 0.76 0.38 0.73 Mundlak corrections Occupational tenure -0.05 0.01 -0.07 0.05 -0.03 0.01 Hours worked -0.03 0.01 -0.04 0.02 -0.02 0.01 Firm size up to 4 -0.02 0.36 -0.17 0.54 0.08 0.40 Firm size 5 to 9 -0.35 0.39 -1.25 1.69 0.22 0.46 Firm size 10 to 19 -0.14 0.37 0.13 0.51 0.63 0.41 Firm size 20 to 49 0.48 0.36 -0.70 0.48 0.09 0.36 Sector Agriculture 0.45 0.80 -2.65 1.24 0.03 0.96 Mining 0.79 1.35 -0.80 1.10 -3.03 1.32 Electricity 0.87 1.43 1.27 2.70 -0.23 1.57 Construction 0.48 0.59 -1.86 1.01 -0.62 0.80 Wholesale -1.08 0.58 -0.08 1.15 0.38 0.65 Retail -0.52 0.47 -0.25 0.82 -0.12 0.67

15

Page 17: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Accommodation -0.20 0.64 0.24 1.46 -0.13 1.32 Transport -0.03 0.60 0.30 0.91 0.09 0.92 Commerce 0.01 0.94 -0.16 1.41 -3.28 2.14 Finance -1.36 0.75 1.63 2.39 -0.91 0.97 Property -0.20 0.52 -2.58 3.07 -0.52 0.55 Defence -0.76 0.72 -1.83 1.21 -0.57 0.66 Education -0.41 0.76 -4.68 2.34 -1.58 0.64 Health -0.89 0.62 -0.99 0.88 -1.00 0.62 Cultural -0.13 0.80 0.98 2.11 -1.33 0.94 Personal 0.85 0.78 -0.11 0.83 -1.98 0.98 Constant 0.72 0.35 0.11 0.49 -0.12 0.36 Initial conditions estimation

Female 0.11 0.13 0.16 0.54 -0.04 0.27 Occupational tenure -0.02 0.01 -0.03 0.06 -0.03 0.02 Hours worked -0.02 0.01 0.00 0.04 -0.05 0.02 Firm size up to 4 0.39 0.27 -0.16 0.70 -0.48 0.51 Firm size 5 to 9 0.33 0.28 -1.09 1.01 -0.82 0.64 Firm size 10 to 19 0.28 0.27 0.54 0.59 -0.55 0.53 Firm size 20 to 49 -0.31 0.24 0.01 0.92 0.24 0.47 Sector Agriculture -0.82 0.60 -0.85 0.80 0.24 1.50 Mining 1.31 1.16 -0.16 2.79 -4.92 3.35 Electricity -7.98 -2.71 4.81 -1.21 3.16 Construction -1.28 0.51 -2.81 2.56 -1.91 1.37 Wholesale 0.33 0.39 -0.75 2.74 -0.20 1.04 Retail -0.02 0.35 0.21 1.94 -0.56 0.87 Accommodation 0.03 0.46 0.14 0.91 -0.32 1.39 Transport 1.02 0.53 0.21 0.94 -1.70 1.44 Commerce -0.51 0.74 -1.89 2.84 3.07 2.01 Finance -0.27 0.66 -41.33 -1.29 1.35 Property -0.71 0.41 -0.48 1.20 -1.06 0.70 Defence -0.01 0.59 -2.64 -2.13 1.19 Education 0.05 0.58 -2.55 2.02 -1.99 1.08 Health -0.83 0.49 -3.37 3.47 -2.23 1.15 Cultural -0.50 0.60 -7.55 9.08 -0.90 1.03 Personal 0.10 0.65 -1.99 1.49 -1.80 1.16 Mundlak corrections Occupational tenure -0.02 0.01 -0.08 0.08 -0.06 0.03 Hours worked -0.02 0.01 -0.05 0.03 0.00 0.02 Firm size up to 4 -0.65 0.33 0.10 0.81 0.98 0.69 Firm size 5 to 9 -0.43 0.34 0.30 1.18 1.20 0.75 Firm size 10 to 19 -0.62 0.35 -1.01 . 0.73 0.71 Firm size 20 to 49 0.44 0.32 -0.41 1.33 -0.06 0.65 Agriculture 0.86 0.68 0.78 -0.38 1.86 Mining -2.59 1.23 -0.63 4.16 4.61 3.31

16

Page 18: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Electricity -1.17 2.19 1.72 4.40 1.11 3.55 Construction 0.91 0.55 2.09 1.90 0.91 1.48 Wholesale -0.34 0.51 -0.13 1.48 0.21 1.33 Retail -0.43 0.42 -0.35 1.55 0.96 1.18 Accommodation -0.11 0.55 -1.34 2.28 1.97 Transport -1.37 0.62 -0.46 2.58 1.70 Commerce 1.34 0.81 2.12 2.22 -2.99 2.26 Finance -0.44 0.73 3.87 4.33 0.07 1.64 Property 0.03 0.49 -1.31 -0.38 0.86 Defence -0.66 0.67 -0.08 2.86 0.70 1.12 Education -1.62 0.67 0.39 2.20 -0.12 1.08 Health -0.22 0.52 2.49 2.96 1.20 1.22 Cultural -0.19 0.71 6.57 7.88 -1.23 1.35 Personal -0.83 0.77 1.23 1.44 -0.32 1.56 Historical variables Immigrant: English spk cntry 0.12 0.19 -0.16 0.67 -0.45 0.35 Immigrant: Non-English spk cntry 0.13 0.17 -1.60 1.74 0.37 0.30 Professional father 0.26 0.13 -0.27 0.57 0.18 0.22 Professional mother -0.41 0.17 -1.09 1.11 -0.46 0.33 Constant 0.96 0.29 0.09 1.03 0.63 0.64 ρ1 0.86 0.04 0.72 0.25 0.56 0.06 θ2 -0.24 0.13 1.91 3.16 1.82 0.58 Restricted Log-L -1883.94 -799.032 -1091.84 Unrestricted Log-L -1781.01 -712.728 -984.187 Cases 9607 5205 9245 Notes: 1 ρ is an estimate of the cross-period correlation of the composite error term

iti u+ε . 2 θ is the statistic used to test if the initial conditions are exogenous. A clearly positive value of θ rejects the hypothesis that the initial conditions are exogenous, thus lending support to the adoption of the Heckman method.

17

Page 19: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

18

References Allen, Jim & van der Velden, Rolf, 2001. “Educational Mismatches versus Skill Mismatches: Effects on Wages, Job Satisfaction, and On-the-job Search,” Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 53(3). Green, F. & McIntosh, S. (2002), Is there a genuine under-utilisation of skills among the over-qualified? SKOPE Research Paper No. 30.

Heckman, J.J. (1981). Heterogeneity and state dependence, in S. Rosen (ed.), Studies in Labor Markets. Chicago, Chicago Press.

Heckman, J. J. (1991). "Identifying the hand of the past: Distinguishing state dependence from heterogeneity" The American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Third Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1991), pp. 75-79.

Jovanovic, B., 1970. “Job Matching and the Theory of Turnover.” Journal of Political Economy 87(5): 972-90.

Lancaster, T. (1979). Duration Analysis, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Mavromaras, K., McGuinness, S. & King, Fok, Y. (2009). “Assessing the Incidence and Wage Effects of Overskilling in the Australian Labour Market”, The Economic Record, 85(268), 60-72.

Mavromaras, K., McGuinness, S., O’Leary, N., Sloane, P. & King, Fok, Y. (2007). “The Problem of Overskilling in Australia and Britain”, forthcoming The Manchester School.

McGuinness, S. & Wooden, M. (2009). “Overskilling, Job Insecurity and Career Mobility: Evidence from Australia”, Industrial Relations, 48(2), 265-286.

McGuinness, S., 2006. Overeducation in the Labour Market. Journal of Economic Surveys 20, 387–418.

O’Leary N., Sloane, P., McGuinness, S., O’Connor P. and Mavromaras, K. (2009), A Taxonomy of Skill Mismatch, Report to CEDEFOP, Thessaloniki.

Rosen, Sherwin. 1972. “Learning and Experience in the Labour Market.” Journal of Human Resources 7(3): 326-42.

Sicherman, N., & Galor, O. 1991. “A Theory of Career Mobility.” Journal of Political Economy 9(2): 101-22.

Sloane, P.J., H. Battu, and P.T. Seaman. 1999. “Overeducation, Undereducation and the British Labour Market.” Applied Economics 31(11): 1437-53.

Sloane, P. (2003). Much ado about nothing? What does the overeducation literature really tell us? In Buchel, de Grip & Mertens (Eds) Overeducation in Europe, pp. 11-49. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.

Page 20: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Year Number Title/Author(s) ESRI Authors/Co-authors Italicised

2009 306 What Determines the Attractiveness of the European Union

to the Location of R&D Multinational Firms? Iulia Siedschlag, Donal Smith, Camelia Turcu, Xiaoheng

Zhang 305 Do Foreign Mergers and Acquisitions Boost Firm

Productivity? Marc Schiffbauer, Iulia Siedschlag, Frances Ruane 304 Inclusion or Diversion in Higher Education in the Republic

of Ireland? Delma Byrne 303 Welfare Regime and Social Class Variation in Poverty and

Economic Vulnerability in Europe: An Analysis of EU-SILC Christopher T. Whelan and Bertrand Maître 302 Understanding the Socio-Economic Distribution and

Consequences of Patterns of Multiple Deprivation: An Application of Self-Organising Maps

Christopher T. Whelan, Mario Lucchini, Maurizio Pisati and Bertrand Maître

301 Estimating the Impact of Metro North Edgar Morgenroth 300 Explaining Structural Change in Cardiovascular Mortality in

Ireland 1995-2005: A Time Series Analysis Richard Layte, Sinead O’Hara and Kathleen Bennett 299 EU Climate Change Policy 2013-2020: Using the Clean

Development Mechanism More Effectively Paul K Gorecki, Seán Lyons and Richard S.J. Tol 298 Irish Public Capital Spending in a Recession Edgar Morgenroth 297 Exporting and Ownership Contributions to Irish

Manufacturing Productivity Growth Anne Marie Gleeson, Frances Ruane 296 Eligibility for Free Primary Care and Avoidable

Hospitalisations in Ireland

19

Page 21: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Anne Nolan 295 Managing Household Waste in Ireland:

Behavioural Parameters and Policy Options John Curtis, Seán Lyons and Abigail O’Callaghan-Platt 294 Labour Market Mismatch Among UK Graduates;

An Analysis Using REFLEX Data Seamus McGuinness and Peter J. Sloane 293 Towards Regional Environmental Accounts for Ireland Richard S.J. Tol , Nicola Commins, Niamh Crilly, Sean

Lyons and Edgar Morgenroth 292 EU Climate Change Policy 2013-2020: Thoughts on

Property Rights and Market Choices Paul K. Gorecki, Sean Lyons and Richard S.J. Tol 291 Measuring House Price Change David Duffy 290 Intra-and Extra-Union Flexibility in Meeting the European

Union’s Emission Reduction Targets Richard S.J. Tol 289 The Determinants and Effects of Training at Work:

Bringing the Workplace Back In Philip J. O’Connell and Delma Byrne 288 Climate Feedbacks on the Terrestrial Biosphere and the

Economics of Climate Policy: An Application of FUND Richard S.J. Tol 287 The Behaviour of the Irish Economy: Insights from the

HERMES macro-economic model Adele Bergin, Thomas Conefrey, John FitzGerald and

Ide Kearney 286 Mapping Patterns of Multiple Deprivation Using

Self-Organising Maps: An Application to EU-SILC Data for Ireland

Maurizio Pisati, Christopher T. Whelan, Mario Lucchini and Bertrand Maître

285 The Feasibility of Low Concentration Targets:

An Application of FUND Richard S.J. Tol

20

Page 22: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

284 Policy Options to Reduce Ireland’s GHG Emissions

Instrument choice: the pros and cons of alternative policy instruments

Thomas Legge and Sue Scott 283 Accounting for Taste: An Examination of Socioeconomic

Gradients in Attendance at Arts Events Pete Lunn and Elish Kelly 282 The Economic Impact of Ocean Acidification on Coral

Reefs Luke M. Brander, Katrin Rehdanz, Richard S.J. Tol, and

Pieter J.H. van Beukering 281 Assessing the impact of biodiversity on tourism flows:

A model for tourist behaviour and its policy implications Giulia Macagno, Maria Loureiro, Paulo A.L.D. Nunes and

Richard S.J. Tol 280 Advertising to boost energy efficiency: the Power of One

campaign and natural gas consumption Seán Diffney, Seán Lyons and Laura Malaguzzi Valeri 279 International Transmission of Business Cycles Between

Ireland and its Trading Partners Jean Goggin and Iulia Siedschlag 278 Optimal Global Dynamic Carbon Taxation David Anthoff 277 Energy Use and Appliance Ownership in Ireland Eimear Leahy and Seán Lyons 276 Discounting for Climate Change David Anthoff, Richard S.J. Tol and Gary W. Yohe 275 Projecting the Future Numbers of Migrant Workers in the

Health and Social Care Sectors in Ireland Alan Barrett and Anna Rust 274 Economic Costs of Extratropical Storms under Climate

Change: An application of FUND Daiju Narita, Richard S.J. Tol, David Anthoff 273 The Macro-Economic Impact of Changing the Rate of

Corporation Tax Thomas Conefrey and John D. Fitz Gerald

21

Page 23: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

272 The Games We Used to Play

An Application of Survival Analysis to the Sporting Life-course

Pete Lunn 2008 271 Exploring the Economic Geography of Ireland Edgar Morgenroth 270 Benchmarking, Social Partnership and Higher

Remuneration: Wage Settling Institutions and the Public-Private Sector Wage Gap in Ireland

Elish Kelly, Seamus McGuinness, Philip O’Connell 269 A Dynamic Analysis of Household Car Ownership in Ireland Anne Nolan 268 The Determinants of Mode of Transport to Work in the

Greater Dublin Area Nicola Commins and Anne Nolan 267 Resonances from Economic Development for Current

Economic Policymaking Frances Ruane 266 The Impact of Wage Bargaining Regime on Firm-Level

Competitiveness and Wage Inequality: The Case of Ireland Seamus McGuinness, Elish Kelly and Philip O’Connell 265 Poverty in Ireland in Comparative European Perspective Christopher T. Whelan and Bertrand Maître 264 A Hedonic Analysis of the Value of Rail Transport in the

Greater Dublin Area Karen Mayor, Seán Lyons, David Duffy and Richard S.J. Tol 263 Comparing Poverty Indicators in an Enlarged EU Christopher T. Whelan and Bertrand Maître 262 Fuel Poverty in Ireland: Extent,

Affected Groups and Policy Issues Sue Scott, Seán Lyons, Claire Keane, Donal McCarthy and

Richard S.J. Tol 261 The Misperception of Inflation by Irish Consumers David Duffy and Pete Lunn

22

Page 24: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

260 The Direct Impact of Climate Change on Regional Labour Productivity

Tord Kjellstrom, R Sari Kovats, Simon J. Lloyd, Tom Holt, Richard S.J. Tol

259 Damage Costs of Climate Change through Intensification

of Tropical Cyclone Activities: An Application of FUND

Daiju Narita, Richard S. J. Tol and David Anthoff 258 Are Over-educated People Insiders or Outsiders?

A Case of Job Search Methods and Over-education in UK Aleksander Kucel, Delma Byrne 257 Metrics for Aggregating the Climate Effect of Different

Emissions: A Unifying Framework Richard S.J. Tol, Terje K. Berntsen, Brian C. O’Neill, Jan S.

Fuglestvedt, Keith P. Shine, Yves Balkanski and Laszlo Makra

256 Intra-Union Flexibility of Non-ETS Emission Reduction

Obligations in the European Union Richard S.J. Tol 255 The Economic Impact of Climate Change Richard S.J. Tol 254 Measuring International Inequity Aversion Richard S.J. Tol 253 Using a Census to Assess the Reliability of a National

Household Survey for Migration Research: The Case of Ireland

Alan Barrett and Elish Kelly 252 Risk Aversion, Time Preference, and the Social Cost of

Carbon David Anthoff, Richard S.J. Tol and Gary W. Yohe 251 The Impact of a Carbon Tax on Economic Growth and

Carbon Dioxide Emissions in Ireland Thomas Conefrey, John D. Fitz Gerald, Laura Malaguzzi

Valeri and Richard S.J. Tol 250 The Distributional Implications of a Carbon Tax in Ireland Tim Callan, Sean Lyons, Susan Scott, Richard S.J. Tol and

Stefano Verde

23

Page 25: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

249 Measuring Material Deprivation in the Enlarged EU Christopher T. Whelan, Brian Nolan and Bertrand Maître 248 Marginal Abatement Costs on Carbon-Dioxide Emissions: A

Meta-Analysis Onno Kuik, Luke Brander and Richard S.J. Tol 247 Incorporating GHG Emission Costs in the Economic

Appraisal of Projects Supported by State Development Agencies

Richard S.J. Tol and Seán Lyons 246 A Carton Tax for Ireland Richard S.J. Tol, Tim Callan, Thomas Conefrey, John D.

Fitz Gerald, Seán Lyons, Laura Malaguzzi Valeri and Susan Scott

245 Non-cash Benefits and the Distribution of Economic Welfare

Tim Callan and Claire Keane 244 Scenarios of Carbon Dioxide Emissions from Aviation Karen Mayor and Richard S.J. Tol 243 The Effect of the Euro on Export Patterns: Empirical

Evidence from Industry Data Gavin Murphy and Iulia Siedschlag 242 The Economic Returns to Field of Study and Competencies

Among Higher Education Graduates in Ireland Elish Kelly, Philip O’Connell and Emer Smyth 241 European Climate Policy and Aviation Emissions Karen Mayor and Richard S.J. Tol 240 Aviation and the Environment in the Context of the EU-US

Open Skies Agreement Karen Mayor and Richard S.J. Tol 239 Yuppie Kvetch? Work-life Conflict and Social Class in

Western Europe Frances McGinnity and Emma Calvert 238 Immigrants and Welfare Programmes: Exploring the

Interactions between Immigrant Characteristics, Immigrant Welfare Dependence and Welfare Policy

Alan Barrett and Yvonne McCarthy 237 How Local is Hospital Treatment? An Exploratory Analysis

24

Page 26: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

of Public/Private Variation in Location of Treatment in Irish Acute Public Hospitals

Jacqueline O’Reilly and Miriam M. Wiley 236 The Immigrant Earnings Disadvantage Across the Earnings

and Skills Distributions: The Case of Immigrants from the EU’s New Member States in Ireland

Alan Barrett, Seamus McGuinness and Martin O’Brien 235 Europeanisation of Inequality and European Reference

Groups Christopher T. Whelan and Bertrand Maître 234 Managing Capital Flows: Experiences from Central and

Eastern Europe Jürgen von Hagen and Iulia Siedschlag 233 ICT Diffusion, Innovation Systems, Globalisation and

Regional Economic Dynamics: Theory and Empirical Evidence

Charlie Karlsson, Gunther Maier, Michaela Trippl, Iulia Siedschlag, Robert Owen and Gavin Murphy

232 Welfare and Competition Effects of Electricity

Interconnection between Great Britain and Ireland Laura Malaguzzi Valeri 231 Is FDI into China Crowding Out the FDI into the European

Union? Laura Resmini and Iulia Siedschlag 230 Estimating the Economic Cost of Disability in Ireland John Cullinan, Brenda Gannon and Seán Lyons 229 Controlling the Cost of Controlling the Climate: The Irish

Government’s Climate Change Strategy Colm McCarthy, Sue Scott 228 The Impact of Climate Change on the Balanced-Growth-

Equivalent: An Application of FUND David Anthoff, Richard S.J. Tol 227 Changing Returns to Education During a Boom? The Case

of Ireland Seamus McGuinness, Frances McGinnity, Philip O’Connell 226 ‘New’ and ‘Old’ Social Risks: Life Cycle and Social Class

Perspectives on Social Exclusion in Ireland

25

Page 27: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

Christopher T. Whelan and Bertrand Maître 225 The Climate Preferences of Irish Tourists by Purpose of

Travel Seán Lyons, Karen Mayor and Richard S.J. Tol 224 A Hirsch Measure for the Quality of Research Supervision,

and an Illustration with Trade Economists Frances P. Ruane and Richard S.J. Tol 223 Environmental Accounts for the Republic of Ireland: 1990-

2005 Seán Lyons, Karen Mayor and Richard S.J. Tol 2007 222 Assessing Vulnerability of Selected Sectors under

Environmental Tax Reform: The issue of pricing power J. Fitz Gerald, M. Keeney and S. Scott 221 Climate Policy Versus Development Aid

Richard S.J. Tol 220 Exports and Productivity – Comparable Evidence for 14

Countries The International Study Group on Exports and Productivity 219 Energy-Using Appliances and Energy-Saving Features:

Determinants of Ownership in Ireland Joe O’Doherty, Seán Lyons and Richard S.J. Tol 218 The Public/Private Mix in Irish Acute Public Hospitals:

Trends and Implications Jacqueline O’Reilly and Miriam M. Wiley

217 Regret About the Timing of First Sexual Intercourse: The

Role of Age and Context Richard Layte, Hannah McGee

216 Determinants of Water Connection Type and Ownership of

Water-Using Appliances in Ireland Joe O’Doherty, Seán Lyons and Richard S.J. Tol

215 Unemployment – Stage or Stigma?

Being Unemployed During an Economic Boom Emer Smyth

214 The Value of Lost Load Richard S.J. Tol

26

Page 28: The data for this paper come from the first six waves of ... with the well-established finding that they also suffer the highest overskilling wage penalty, ... temporary phenomenon,

27

213 Adolescents’ Educational Attainment and School Experiences in Contemporary Ireland Merike Darmody, Selina McCoy, Emer Smyth

212 Acting Up or Opting Out? Truancy in Irish Secondary

Schools Merike Darmody, Emer Smyth and Selina McCoy

211 Where do MNEs Expand Production: Location Choices of

the Pharmaceutical Industry in Europe after 1992 Frances P. Ruane, Xiaoheng Zhang

210 Holiday Destinations: Understanding the Travel Choices of

Irish Tourists Seán Lyons, Karen Mayor and Richard S.J. Tol

209 The Effectiveness of Competition Policy and the Price-Cost

Margin: Evidence from Panel Data Patrick McCloughan, Seán Lyons and William Batt

208 Tax Structure and Female Labour Market Participation:

Evidence from Ireland Tim Callan, A. Van Soest, J.R. Walsh

207 Distributional Effects of Public Education Transfers in

Seven European Countries Tim Callan, Tim Smeeding and Panos Tsakloglou