Ferner Power

download Ferner Power

of 43

Transcript of Ferner Power

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    1/43

    Forthcoming inHuman Relations, February 2012. Pre-publication draft provided

    for information and private study only.

    Power, institutions and the cross-national transfer of employment practices in

    multinationals

    Anthony Ferner, Tony Edwards and Anne Tempel

    Abstract

    This paper argues for the systematic incorporation of power and interests into analysis

    of the cross-border transfer of practices within multinational companies (MNCs). Using

    a broadly Lukesian perspective on power it is argued that the transfer of practices

    involves different kinds of power capabilities through which MNC actors influence

    their institutional environment both at the macro-level of host institutions and the

    micro-level of the MNC itself. The incorporation of an explicit account of the way

    power interacts with institutions at different levels, it is suggested, underpins a more

    convincing account of transfer than is provided by the dominant neoinstitutionalist

    perspective in international business, and leads to a heuristic model capable of

    generating proposed patterns of transfer outcomes that may be tested empirically in

    future research.

    Keywords

    multinationals; comparative & cross-cultural HRM; conflict; international HRM;

    strategic and international management; organisational theory.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    2/43

    Introduction

    Much has been written about the cross-national transfer of management practices in

    multinational companies (MNCs). A recent conceptual development is the neoinstitutionalist

    contribution of Kostova and colleagues (Kostova, 1999; Kostova and Roth, 2002; Kostova et

    al., 2008). In the international business literature, this approach shows signs of establishing a

    new intellectual hegemony.1 Given this salience, critical engagement is essential.

    The neoinstitutionalist approach to practice transfer in MNCs has provided fundamental

    insights. It argues that MNCs or to be more precise, their subsidiaries operate under

    conditions of institutional duality, facing both the institutional terrain of the international firm

    itself and that of the host environment in which they operate. These institutional spheres exert

    rival isomorphic pressures which come to the fore when practices are transferred from the

    parent to host operations. Drawing on Scotts (2008) institutional pillars, Kostova uses the

    country institutional profile tool to characterize parent- and host-country institutions. This

    provides the basis for assessing institutional distance (ID), the divergence in institutional

    arrangements between the parent country and host. In general, the greater the ID, the more

    problematic is transfer; and the harder is the internalization of transferred practices, that is,

    their full assimilation to host employees cognitive mindsets and normative frameworks

    (Kostova, 1999).

    However, neoinstitutionalist positions on transfer in MNCs suffer from a neglect of old

    institutionalist questions about power, coalitions, interests and competing value systems (e.g.

    Stinchcombe, 1997), despite increasing attention to such questions in broader neoinstitutionalist

    theory (e.g. Oliver, 1991; Greenwood and Hinings, 1996; Lawrence, 2008; Lounsbury, 2003;

    Tempel and Walgenbach, 2007). The key concepts of institutional duality and institutional

    distance overlook the ability of actors in MNCs to shape institutions to their needs and thus

    influence the transfer process. There is little sense of what is at stake for actors in the

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    3/43

    confrontation of cognitive, normative and regulative frameworks that arise when practices are

    transferred.

    This paper discusses how the analysis of power can be incorporated into an understanding of

    cross-institutional practice transfer. It builds on recent work concerning MNCs as political

    actors (e.g. Blanger and Edwards, 2006; Drrenbcher and Gammelgaard, 2011; Drrenbcher

    and Geppert, 2011; Edwards and Blanger, 2009; Ferner and Edwards, 1995; Ferner and

    Tempel, 2006; Levy, 2008; Levy and Egan, 2003). It argues that power and interests of actors

    shape transfer through processes that draw on institutional resources both at the macro level of

    the host business system and the micro level of the MNC. These processes in turn shape the

    transformations and adaptations undergone by transferred practices. Power, it is suggested, has

    to be understood in its institutional context, both in that it is deployed by powerful MNC actors

    to shape, sustain and activate macro- and micro-level institutions a process that

    neoinstitutionalists refer to as institutional work (Lawrence and Suddaby, 2006); and in that

    institutional context provides actors with power capabilities with which to facilitate, block or

    modify transfer.

    The cross-national transfer of practices in MNCs is complex, with an array of possible

    outcomes. Transfer has several dimensions: the degree of adaptation or hybridization of

    practices; internalization; functionality; and directionality. The first of these refers to the fact

    that transfer is not an either/or issue; there may be degrees of transfer. The transferred practice

    may be modified in the course of implementation, or it may be hybridized, that is, combined

    with host practices (e.g. Becker-Ritterspach, 2009). Internalization denotes that, even where a

    practice is transferred in its original form, it may be assimilated to a greater or lesser extent to

    the working assumptions, cognitive understandings and normative frameworks of subsidiary

    employees and managers. Functionality refers to the degree to which transferred practices

    perform the function intended for them by powerful HQ actors, or work in ways that these

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    4/43

    actors would consider to be unintended or dysfunctional. Finally, directionality indicates that

    transfer does not occur solely from HQ to subsidiary, but also between subsidiaries themselves,

    or from subsidiaries to HQ. Thus various outcomes are possible, and one of the principal aims

    of this paper is to provide a conceptual framework for understanding how power relations in

    MNCs influence the outcomes of practice transfer between different institutional domains.

    The paper illustrates the argument with empirical examples drawn from human resource and

    employment practices (HR&EP) in MNCs. The rationale is twofold. First, the cross-national

    dissemination of such practices is increasingly seen in a knowledge-based global economy as

    key for international competitive advantage (e.g. Lado and Wilson, 1994). Second, however,

    HR&EP are particularly subject to host institutional influence (e.g. Rosenzweig and Nohria,

    1994). Moreover, relations between employers and workforces are characterized by a

    structured antagonism (Edwards, 1986) providing the basis for the ongoing exercise of power

    and resistance in relation to HR&EP; this structured antagonism is carried into the international

    sphere, on to the contested terrain of the MNC (Blanger and Edwards, 2009).

    The paper first discusses a conceptualization of power in relation to MNCs. Second, it examines

    power capabilities and interests of different groups of actors within the MNC, in particular at

    HQ and subsidiary level. Finally, it marshals the arguments on power, interests and institutions

    to explore different transfer outcomes.

    Power and MNCs

    MNCs are powerful actors, driving economic activity in many sectors and one of the motive

    forces of globalization. They are also complex organizations, marked by the dispersion of

    power among groups, functions and operating units (e.g. Blanger and Edwards, 2009;

    Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2011; Ferner and Tempel, 2006). In particular, the respective power

    of HQ and subsidiaries makes for the negotiation of relationships within the MNC (Ferner and

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    5/43

    Edwards, 1995). MNC actors manoeuvre among institutional contradictions that leave

    considerable scope for praxis (Geppert and Drrenbcher, 2011). Transfer can be viewed as a

    specific instance of HQsubsidiary relations, in which the power capabilities of actors at each

    level influence outcomes. How are such capabilities to be conceptualized?

    This paper builds on a Lukesian perspective (Lukes, 1975; 2005) that identifies three

    dimensions of power. Each may be related to the behaviour of MNC actors in the realm of

    practice transfer. The first concerns the nature of decisions that are made, and the deployment

    of resources to affect them. The second relates to conflicts around non-decisions, reflecting

    the ability of powerful actors to shape the agenda, exclude or include issues, and determine the

    processes and rules by which decisions are arrived at. The third concerns the way in which

    powerful actors exercise domination over others by influencing, shaping or determining [their]

    very wants (Lukes, 1975: 27).

    As Lukes admits (2005: ch3), the notion of power as domination over other actors who may

    consentto domination requires the imputation of real interests to actors (i.e. interests that are

    masked by the third dimension of power). Given the difficulties of the undertaking, he argues

    (p148) that what count as real interests [is] a function of ones explanatory purpose,

    framework and methods. Without wishing to get enmeshed in this debate, we would note that

    the paper is premised on the notion that interests are constructedby MNC actors in ways that

    are variable and issue-specific, and the process gives rise to bundles of interests that are

    complex and not necessarily internally coherent (cf. Lukes, 2005: ch3). There may be a

    hierarchy of interests, with economic security or survival, for example, being a primary and

    persisting interest for most actors. Beyond that, interests may be more changeable and context-

    dependent. Such interests may be collective, emerging, for example, around a particular model

    of teamworking in a subsidiary that allocates particular roles to different groups of employees,

    supervisors and managers; orindividual, deriving notably from personal and biographical

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    6/43

    considerations to do with career paths and aspirations within the MNC, rather than from

    organizational or group affiliations (see e.g. Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2009a).

    Hardy (1996) has applied a Lukesian model to a business context, and her terminology is

    adopted here. She labels the first dimension the power of resources, which concerns power

    derived from the control of scarce resources, such as hiring and firing, rewards and sanctions,

    and expertise, in order to influence behaviour in the face of opposition. The second, the power

    of processes, resides in organizational decision making processes which incorporate a variety

    of procedures and political routines that can be invoked by dominant groups to influence

    outcomes by preventing subordinates from participating fully in decision making (p7); equally,

    new groups may be brought, or force their way, into decision-making processes. The third

    dimension is labelled the power of meaning; Hardy explores the way in which organizational

    groups legitimize their own demands and delegitimize those of others through the

    management of meaning and the deployment of symbolic actions. As a result, actors may be

    impeded from exercising agency. As Levy argues (2008; also Levy and Egan, 2003), the control

    of meaning has important linkages with the Gramscian concept of hegemony (Gramsci, 1971),

    emphasizing that the control of meaning, or the discursive realm, relates to power relations in

    the real economic and technological realms. In other words, in the case of MNCs, the power of

    meaning is built upon the resource power that derives from the primary economic activity of the

    firm and its constituent parts. This third dimension of power also provides a crucial link with

    neoinstitutionalist analysis, by illuminating in particular how the cognitive and normative

    pillars (Scott, 2008) of institutional arrangements embody power relations and serve the

    interests of powerful actors, and how such pillars may be susceptible to contestation rather than

    being seen as external givens.

    While all three dimensions of power are important for an understanding of cross-institutional

    transfer, the power of meaning is especially crucial. When institutionalized practices are

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    7/43

    transferred cross-nationally, this hidden dimension is rendered visible (Ferner et al., 2005) by

    the collision of two sets of institutional rationalities. Transfer thus creates an important

    condition for the exercise of agency: that actors become conscious of taken-for-granted

    institutional processes (e.g. Clemens and Cook, 1999; Seo and Creed, 2002). In short, transfer

    leads to potential conflicts of institutional rationality that are resolved through the deployment

    of power capabilities. For example, individual performance appraisal and reward is a norm

    taken for granted and generally regarded as legitimate in liberal market economies. Even if

    disliked, it can only be legitimately challenged on grounds of its failure to achieve its

    performance-enhancing functions. But cross-institutional transfer allows the shared norms to be

    laid bare and challenged on grounds of alternative normative frameworks, emphasizing (for

    example) social equity, solidarity and fairness (e.g. Liberman and Torbiorn, 2000).

    MNC actors in situations of transfer: Power capabilities and organizational interests

    To understand transfer outcomes in the context of power relations, two questions must be

    addressed. First, what power capabilities do actors in MNCs possess? As an initial

    approximation, we explore the power capabilities of actors at HQ compared with those of the

    subsidiary. This reflects the thrust of arguments (e.g. Geppert and Drrenbcher, 2011;

    Kristensen and Zeitlin, 2005; Morgan and Kristensen, 2006) that the relationship between the

    HQ and subsidiary constitute a primary axis of power relations within MNCs.

    Second, what interests are constructed or present in relation to transferred practices? The

    answer to this question requires a more nuanced analysis of actors at HQ and subsidiary level. It

    determines whether, given respective power capabilities, the subsidiary acts as part of a

    monolithic MNC bloc vis--vis host institutions, seeking ways of overcoming institutional

    constraints; or opposes HQs efforts to transfer. Also possible is some complex configuration of

    interests where some groups in the subsidiary support transfer, while others oppose it (and the

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    8/43

    same may be true of HQ actors). In other words, interests determine how power capabilities are

    deployed in relation to transfer.

    We first explore the power capabilities of MNCs as unitary entities with common

    organizational interests (Morgan, 2011) vis--vis the macro-institutional settings in which they

    operate. We then relax the assumption of unity and analyse separately the capabilities of HQ

    and subsidiary actors. Finally we examine the array of interests that are likely to be constructed

    around HR&EP practice transfer.

    The power of MNCs to shape macro-institutional settings

    The Kostovian approach to transfer neglects the power of MNCs to shape macro-institutional

    settings on two key counts. The first concerns the broader systemic context within which

    institutional duality is played out. Smith and Meiksins (1995) argue that the underlying global

    dynamics of capitalist development create system effects that may be distinguished from

    institutional variations, or societal effects.

    The global economic system, and the associated concepts of globalization, the world market,

    competition, and so on, are themselves the highly institutionalized outcome of the active agency

    (e.g. Campbell, 2004: ch.5) of powerful actors, including states, supranational bodies and

    MNCs (e.g. Djelic and Quack, 2003; Levy and Egan, 2003). As Morgan (2011; also Sklair,

    2001) argues, an emerging global managerial elite has assumed an important role in

    international standard-setting and transnational institution building. MNCs have played an

    important role in building this context. Sell (2000), for example, shows the role of US

    multinationals in shaping the rules of international commerce on TRIPS (Trade-related aspects

    of intellectual property rights) and GATS (General Agreement on Trade in Services) (see also

    Djelic and Quack, 2003).

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    9/43

    The interrelationship between the global system and national institutional spaces has

    implications for transfer. In particular, the world economic system is hierarchically structured

    by the power of national actors (Smith and Meiksins, 1995). Dominance effects allude to the

    influence of practices developed in leading economies, sectors or firms. They influence all three

    dimensions of power. MNCs from dominant business systems have greater resource power by

    virtue of their economic success. They have power over processes that facilitates transfer. Such

    power can be at a systemic level through their ability to shape the decision-making rules

    governing international economic activity. It can also be more immediate, for example through

    the concentrated presence of MNCs from a dominant economy in a host country, as in the case

    of the dense networks of US subsidiaries in the UK or Ireland. This presence creates a stratum

    of organizations familiar with parent-country practices, and a pool of employees and managers

    with appropriate cognitive and normative expertise.

    Dominance also shapes systems of meaning as the dominant power becomes hegemonic. On

    the one hand, it creates a presumption by actors from dominant countries and firms that their

    practices have superior efficacy, providing a motive for transfer. On the other, this view may be

    shared by actors in the host, including policy-makers, subsidiary managers and workforces, and

    hence increase receptiveness to transfer. Thus transfer is smoothed because practices are

    accorded legitimacy by a wide range of MNC actors and are regarded as global best practices

    (e.g. Pudelko and Harzing, 2007). One may therefore expect that where the transferred practice

    derives from a parent country that is dominant vis--vis the host, the inhibiting effect of ID on

    transfer will be reduced.

    Dominance effects evolve. One illustration of this is that the dominant position of US

    carmakers in the period immediately after the Second World War had been lost by the 1970s

    and 1980s, with Japanese firms assuming dominant status. Indeed, the Japanese economy as a

    whole achieved a dominant position in the 1980s, albeit briefly; with Japans Lost Decade and

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    10/43

    major corporate bankruptcies, the US regained a position of dominance, although the conditions

    that underpinned this renewed dominance, such as easy access to cheap capital, also proved

    transient (Schwartz, 2009), illustrating the dynamic nature of dominance effects.

    Dominance, moreover, is felt at sectoral level as well as at the level of business systems as a

    whole. As the above discussion implies, American MNCs should not be seen as dominant

    across all sectors. The point that national institutional configurations provide conducive

    conditions for firms to flourish in some sectors but not in others is central to the varieties of

    capitalism literature (Hall and Soskice, 2001) and also has a long history in economics through

    the theory of comparative advantage. The success of US MNCs in sectors like IT and

    pharmaceuticals, together with the relative decline of American firms in sectors like consumer

    durables and automotives, confirms this. In short, dominance effects, even of the hegemonic

    economic power, are likely to be particularly strong in the sectors in which it has a competitive

    advantage, and weaker or absent in others.

    Secondly, Kostova and colleagues neglect that MNCs as powerful organizations commonly act

    as rule-makers as well as rule-takers (Streeck and Thelen, 2005) vis--vis host institutional

    contexts. Rule-makers are actors involved in setting and modifying in conflict and

    competition, the rules with which [rule-takers] are expected to comply (p13). MNCs routinely

    engage in what Oliver (1991) calls manipulation of institutional settings, exerting direct

    pressures on the sphere of policy-making (e.g. DeVos, 1981, on attempts by US MNCs in

    Germany to influence reform of codetermination legislation). Sometimes such pressure and

    rule-making is passive: in other words, host actors adapt institutional rules to what they see as

    the preferences of MNCs, without active intervention by the latter. An example is the move by

    the Irish authorities in the 1980s away from the previous policy of encouraging incoming

    MNCs to adopt post-entry closed shop union agreements and to bargain collectively; the change

    reflected the desire of policy-makers to promote rules they considered attractive to a new wave

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    11/43

    of largely US direct investors in sectors such as pharmaceuticals, electronics and IT where such

    provisions were seen as hampering investment (Gunnigle et al., 2006).

    Moreover, MNCs may shape institutions in more bottom-up fashion through their distinctive

    practice (e.g. Djelic and Quack, 2003). Thus the scope for macro-institutional manoeuvre may

    exist even in highly-regulated institutional settings such as Germany. MNCs have been able to

    find space (e.g. Singe and Croucher, 2005; Tempel et al., 2006) by exploiting weaknesses in

    formal institutions such as works councils that are quite heterogeneous in their operations

    (Kotthoff, 1994); and as Streeck and Thelen (2005: 14) argue, there is always a gap between

    the ideal pattern of a rule and the real pattern of life under it; thus the rules of codetermination

    in Germany are characterized by deep ambiguities reflecting the conditions under which they

    had been drawn up. MNCs power to shape processes and structures through which decisions

    are made is seen in their ability to engage in what Streeck and Thelen (2005) call institutional

    layering and conversion, whereby existing structures are bypassed, or subtly changed in

    function. Singe and Croucher (2005) in their synthesis of research on US firms in Germany

    suggest these firms adopted a dichotomous approach of formal compliance combined with

    content avoidance towards codetermination institutions, deploying power resources to

    colonize works councils and exert high levels of pressure on works councillors to divorce

    themselves from unions (p134). US subsidiaries have moved between bargaining jurisdictions

    to leverage distinctions in how these operate; in one such firm, the German subsidiarys deft

    institutional manoeuvring allowed it to be the first subsidiary in Europe to implement the

    MNCs global variable pay model (Tempel et al., 2006).

    Even where regulative systems potentially constrain action, regulations need to be invoked and

    enforced. In Germany or Spain, works-council-style representation has to be triggered by the

    workforce. There is thus a terrain of action for management to deploy power to avoid macro-

    institutional coercive pressures. Managers can use power over resources to raise the costs for

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    12/43

    the workforce of invoking statutory rights; thus the Spanish subsidiary of a US MNC threatened

    to offer only minimum statutory redundancy pay if the workforce activated its right to union

    representation during the redundancy process (Colling et al., 2006). Therefore, actors are

    involved in a process of deploying power capabilities more or less creatively on a particular

    institutional terrain.

    MNCs are able to engage in institutional arbitrage (Morgan et al., 2003), manoeuvring

    between institutional variations within a given host setting, assembling and reassembling

    institutional elements in a process of bricolage to create new variants. In sectors most exposed

    to global competition, such as finance and business services (Morgan, 2009), or in periods of

    institutional instability, MNCs may have greater freedom to create innovative institutional

    arrangements within the dominant host framework, leading to what Thelen (2009) calls the

    segmentation of business systems.

    The ability of powerful institutional entrepreneurs, including MNCs, to shape institutional

    settings is a key factor in a current strand of comparative institutionalism that questions the

    monolithic character of national-institutional configurations and emphasizes internal

    heterogeneity (e.g. Almond, 2011; Crouch et al., 2009; Lane and Wood, 2009; Saka, 2002). For

    Crouch (2005; Crouch et al., 2009) intra-model variety is the norm rather than an anomaly,

    hence firms may be less bound by national constraints than much theory suggests. In practice,

    institutional elements are more loose-coupled, and the national model less determinant.

    Heterogeneity has substantial implications for the Kostovian concepts of institutional distance

    and country institutional profile. While multiplicity in institutional settings has been discussed

    by neoinstitutionalists (e.g. Clemens and Cook, 1999; Delmestri, 2009; Oliver, 1991) and is

    acknowledged by Kostova et al. (2008: 997), the implications for transfer have not been

    thoroughly assimilated (cf. Phillips et al., 2009). Chief among them is that MNCs rule-making

    capacity within institutional configurations may facilitate the transfer of practices even to

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    13/43

    institutionally distant hosts. The overall country institutional profile may not be the

    appropriate level of analysis, and more fine-grained examination of local host arrangements

    may be needed. An alternative instrument, based on constructing the institutional profile of the

    subnational variant, would seem to offer a conceptual way forward, although practical problems

    may be foreseen of access to adequate subnational data on institutional arrangements.

    Power capabilities of MNC actors

    Turning now to classify the power capabilities2 of MNC actors in situations of transfer, these

    capabilities may be derived from the micro-institutionaldomain of the MNC itself, or from

    macro-institutional arrangements in the host (and beyond). Crucially, MNCs may use power to

    shape macro-level institutions, affecting the processes whereby they are established, maintained

    over time, revised in function or scope, or replaced by other arrangements (e.g. Knight, 1992;

    Lawrence, 2008; Lawrence and Suddaby, 2006).

    Agency is not confined to HQ policy-makers. Actors in the subsidiary have their own sources of

    power. Where power capabilities of different kinds are disseminated across organizational

    levels, groups and individuals within a MNC, pressures to adopt transferred practices are

    susceptible to deflection, avoidance, negotiation or challenge by subordinate actors (cf. Oliver,

    1991). In order to predict transfer outcomes, it is therefore necessary to assess the balance of

    capabilities between the centre and the subsidiary (Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2009b).

    However, while there has been much discussion of the decentred or networked nature of

    contemporary MNCs (e.g. Andersson and Holm, 2010) an authoritative central HQ remains the

    norm. As Egelhoff (2010) argues, network structures provide inadequate vertical

    specialization, which is required to perform functions such as providing accountability to

    shareholders and imposing tight-coupled coordination on units where careful synchronization

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    14/43

    of operations is required. Thus, the overall power of HQ positions it as a field dominant (e.g.

    Levy, 2008) in relation to the organizational field constituted by the MNC.

    The power capabilities of headquarters actors. HQ actors have specific capabilities relating

    to each of the dimensions of power. The first aspect of HQ micro-institutional power is control

    of the allocation among subsidiaries of key organizational resources, such as finance,

    investment, and knowledge and expertise, through budgeting and management control

    processes. Decisions over resource allocation have critical impacts on the economic security

    and survival of subsidiaries. HQ also controls career opportunities and rewards of key

    subsidiary actors; recalcitrance may jeopardize remuneration or career advancement,

    particularly where aspirations are international (e.g. Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2009a).

    However, as discussed below, power resources are unlikely to be monopolized by HQ.

    Moreover, the big guns at HQs disposal, such as the threat of closure or investment

    allocation, may be disproportionate weapons for resolving downstream conflicts over the

    transfer of HR practices; and the threat of closure may be unavailable if an MNCs investment

    is market-seeking or resource-seeking, rather than efficiency-seeking. If a subsidiary is

    performing well economically, it is less likely to be penalized for not adopting transferred HR

    practices. Conversely, poorly-performing subsidiaries are more vulnerable to pressure from HQ

    to conform (e.g. Tempel et al., 2006). Thus there is considerable scope for HQsubsidiary

    negotiation (cf. Ferner and Edwards, 1995).

    Turning, second, to power of processes, within the MNC there is a transnational authority

    structure that legitimates the exercise of power by hierarchically senior actors (units, groups,

    individuals, etc.). Formal hierarchical authority shapes the way decisions are made and

    resources allocated within the firm (cf. Hardy, 1996). HQs role as apex of the authority

    structure gives it the power to determine mechanisms for transferring practices to subsidiaries

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    15/43

    abroad. In particular, it can specify which actors at which level are able to intervene in

    decisions, for example on the introduction of a new global HR policy. Decision-making rules

    frame how practices are codified into policy and transferred to subsidiaries. Generally, HQ can

    define formal policies for subsidiaries with a prima facie expectation that subsidiaries comply.

    It can impose enforcement and monitoring mechanisms and benchmark practice across

    subsidiaries, facilitating transfer.

    Finally, HQ has power over meaning. It can influence cognitive and normative aspects of the

    micro-institutional frame of action by shaping corporate cultures, codes of practice and standard

    operating procedures, which then become institutionalized. This third face of power helps

    shape the mindsets of those in subsidiaries whose job it is to implement transferred policy.

    Research suggests that formal policies need shared understandings in order to function

    effectively (Ferner, 2000). HQ actors control the creation of legitimatory rhetorics (Suddaby

    and Greenwood, 2005) concerning, for instance, competitive advantage, profitability, or site

    closures (Erkama and Vaara, 2010). This is important where there is causal ambiguity about

    the impact of a transferred practice in the subsidiary (Szulanski, 1996), which may be the case

    particularly for downstream activities such as HR (Boxall and Purcell, 2011). HQ actors can

    also shape meaning systems in subsidiaries by, for example, recruiting key host individuals

    whose mindsets are less typical of host norms and more in tune with organizational norms

    (Evans and Lorange, 1989); this allows them to bypass barriers to internalization and helps

    create alternative micro-institutional settings within the host institutional context.

    The power capabilities of subsidiary actors Subsidiary actors have the capacity to challenge

    transfer and protect host institutional arrangements. There has been much work in recent years

    conceptualizing subsidiaries as active strategizers within the wider MNC (e.g. Blanger et al.,

    1999; Bouquet and Birkinshaw, 2008; Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2009b; Drrenbcher and

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    16/43

    Gammelgaard, 2011; Kristensen and Zeitlin, 2005; Morgan and Kristensen, 2006), rather than

    passive transmission belts for HQ policies and practices. The ability to strategize depends on

    power capabilities stemming from both the micro-level of the MNC and the macro-level of the

    host institutional environment.

    Considering first the micro-political power of subsidiary actors, subsidiaries may achieve power

    over resources from the competent performance of their productive activities (e.g. Andersson

    and Forsgren, 1996). For example, they may generate a substantial proportion of the MNCs

    profit,3 offer access to key markets, create competitively significant knowledge or expertise, or

    perform functions that are critical to the success of the firms value chain (Drrenbcher and

    Gammelgaard, 2011). Possession of resources allows subsidiaries to negotiate to some degree

    its relationship with HQ.

    Power over processes is primarily the province of HQ and the hierarchical authority structure,

    but not exclusively so. Subsidiaries may use their bargaining power deriving from control of

    resources to achieve a modification of decision-making processes, with an impact on transfers.

    For example, in a US engineering firm, HR managers from subsidiaries generating a large

    proportion of global revenue won a revision of the policy-making process that accorded them a

    greater role in the definition of global HR policies (Edwards, T. et al., 2007). In terms of

    transfer, the exercise of process power is likely to result in policies that are more sensitive to

    host institutions, and hence more easily transferable.

    HQ is also likely to dominate power over meaning, yet subsidiaries again may have some

    influence at least to contestdominant systems of meaning within the organization. The transfer

    of practices and their associated meaning systems across institutional spaces makes visible

    taken-for-granted normative and cognitive frameworks and hence renders them susceptible to

    purposive action. One example is the transfer of workforce diversity policies to the UK

    subsidiaries of US MNCs. Transfer exposed underlying discourses concerning the business

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    17/43

    case and equal employment opportunities, through the collision of very different diversity

    rationalities in the US and the UK (Ferner et al., 2005). Another instance is an attempt by an

    American business services firm to implement a global performance-related pay scheme for

    professional consultant staff in the German subsidiary. These employees strongly opposed the

    new system which clashed with normative frameworks of fairness and was seen as leading to

    culturally unacceptable pay differentials (Almond et al., 2006: 138-9).

    MNCs micro-institutions are beset with ambiguities, complexities and inconsistencies,

    particularly when applied to real choices in a complex business world. These give actors room

    for idiosyncratic interpretation of norms and rules. Even if subsidiaries do not have the power to

    shape micro-institutional frameworks of meaning, they can selectively respond to different parts

    of a complex configuration. In short, rival micro-institutional norms provide alternative

    rhetorics legitimating or de-legitimating particular courses of action (Suddaby and

    Greenwood, 2005).

    Within the HR function, whose activities are largely downstream, one source of ambiguity is

    that they may be only partially nested within upstream strategic objectives related to

    competition, profitability and growth. In other words, they may have relative autonomy.

    HR&EP norms may be at odds with upstream norms concerning economic performance, and

    can be deflected on that basis. Where transferred HR practices are seen as disrupting existing

    relationships or practices regarded as functional for subsidiary performance, subsidiary actors

    may deploy what Suddaby and Greenwood (2005) term ontological rhetorics asserting the

    existential incompatibility of economic goals and transferred HR practices. Even within the HR

    domain, there may be contradictions within highly complex normative frameworks; for

    example, between principles of pay determination and approaches to union recognition. Thus

    UK subsidiary managers in one US MNC resisted a global pay freeze on the grounds that it

    conflicted with a competing corporate norm of favouring non-union employee relations

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    18/43

    (Almond and Ferner, 2006). In short, subsidiary actors can exploit rival appeals to legitimacy

    within the MNC, and are likely to do so when they oppose transfer.

    Turning to macro-institutional resources, subsidiary actors derive power capabilities from their

    status as skilled negotiators of the host institutional context, both of the overarching national-

    institutional framework, and the subnational niches and variants in which they are located.

    Where the subsidiary operates essentially as the willing local agent of the wider MNC, these

    powers may be used to promote transfer. However, where conflicts of interest exist between

    subsidiary and HQ, the same capacities may be used to block or amend transferred practices.

    First, subsidiaries derive power resources from the institutional complementarities (Hall and

    Soskice, 2001) of the host business system that generate certain competitive advantages. Given

    the increasing importance of intra-model variants, subsidiaries local embeddedness is often

    crucial for the generation of resources such as scarce knowledge and expertise of value to the

    economic activity of the MNC, and that the MNC cannot otherwise access (Andersson and

    Forsgren, 1996; Drrenbcher, and Gammelgaard, 2010; Sorge and Rothe, 2011). Almond

    (2011) points to the significance of locally embedded flexible high-skills ecosystems that

    drive innovation and provide actors with power resources for shaping practice transfer.

    Second, the regulatory framework of the host gives subsidiary actors some purchase over the

    power of process by exerting coercive isomorphic pressures, for example in employment

    relations and the workings of the labour market. Thus German codetermination legislation gives

    employees rights to representation on company supervisory boards, and to set up works

    councils with statutory rights over a range of work-related issues. Changes to payment systems

    resulting from transferred pay and performance practices are subject to codetermination. Even

    where the MNC deploys resources to mitigate this loss of process control (see above), it

    nonetheless increases the costs for MNCs of shaping decisions, and necessitates some degree of

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    19/43

    negotiation with local actors and/or the application of power resources. Thus the power of

    process provides subsidiary actors with a capability to resist practice transfer.

    Third, subsidiary actors are able to exploit host institutional settings to challenge dominant

    actors power of meaning in the MNC. In particular, significant macro-institutional capabilities

    derive from subsidiary actors competence as skilled interpreters of the host institutional frame.

    In other words, they can shape the normative and cognitive understandings of what is possible,

    desirable and contextually rational. Even the most highly regulated and juridified systems leave

    spaces for interpretation based on expert institutional knowledge. More subtle and tacit

    cognitive and normative elements of institutional frameworks are even more subject to insider

    exegesis. While subsidiary actors may use such institutional expertise to further transfer, in

    situations of interest conflict with HQ, they may equally draw on such capabilities to construct a

    rhetoric legitimating opposition to transfer.

    Naturally, subsidiary actors interpretations of the viability of transfer are liable to challenge

    and counter-interpretation, notably by expatriate managers, and sceptical HQ actors may

    demand that local managers claims be thoroughly tested. This may especially be the case

    where dominance effects are present, notably in US MNCs which may have a strong

    presumption of the efficacy of HQ practices (e.g. Almond et al., 2006; Tempel et al., 2006).

    Again, therefore, the host institutional context provides a contested terrain (cf. Edwards and

    Blanger, 2009; also Geppert and Drrenbcher, 2011), in which interest groups at different

    levels within the MNC struggle to further their agendas.

    A final point concerning the power capabilities of subsidiary actors is that their issue-scope of

    power (Lukes, 2005: 74-5) - the range of issues over which an actor can determine outcomes -

    is likely to be limited because of the overall power of HQ. As a result subsidiaries are likely to

    have to prioritize the issues over which they expend capabilities that are scarce relative to those

    of HQ actors. Moreover, their power is likely (again using Lukes terminology) to have a lower

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    20/43

    contextual range, to be largely restricted to the specific institutional setting in which they

    operate; whereas that of HQ is likely to be more context-transcending, deployable under a

    wider range of circumstances, especially where dominance effects come into play. A possible

    exception to this is where the subsidiary is located in a host that is more dominant in the

    global economy than is the MNCs country of origin. This may provide greater context-

    transcending capacity to the subsidiary, leading for example to additional possible transfer

    outcomes such as reverse diffusion (Edwards and Ferner, 2004) in which practices are

    transferred from subsidiary to HQ.

    These arguments are summarized in Table 1.

    [Table 1 about here]

    MNC actors and interests in the context of HR&EP transfer

    We are now in a position to examine HQ and subsidiary interests in relation to transfer.

    Together with the power capacities of HQ and subsidiary explored above, the constellation of

    interests will determine the stance of subsidiary actors towards transferred practices.

    Who are the relevant MNC actors in situations of institutional duality and transfer? A first

    approximation is to divide actors into those associated with the headquarters perspective and

    those in the subsidiary. In reality, finer-grained distinctions may become necessary to include

    for example actors at regional or business-unit headquarters with interests and power

    capabilities distinguishable both from those of corporate headquarters and national subsidiaries.

    Moreover, HQ is not a homogeneous block but comprises different groupings (e.g. by

    management function and level) with potentially different interests in relation to transfer.

    At subsidiary level, a core distinction is between managers and workforce (Edwards and

    Blanger, 2009). There may be both common and divergent interests. Managers and workforce

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    21/43

    may both have an interest in the sites survival, for example. In contrast, particularly where the

    impact of a transferred practice on the sites performance is ambiguous or contested, interests

    may diverge. Depending on the practice, further disaggregation may be appropriate; for

    example, subsidiary operations managers may see the transfer of practices such as teamworking

    as useful for efficiency while HR managers may oppose transfer on the grounds that they

    disrupt existing accommodation with employees. An important distinction is between managers

    whose career ambit lies within the host country and those whose careers trajectories and

    aspirations are international in scope (Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2009a; Morgan and

    Kristensen, 2006). The former may engage in subversive strategizing (Kristensen and Zeitlin,

    2005), acting counter to HQ norms and prescriptions in order to strengthen the effectiveness of

    the subsidiary; while the latter may have less stake in the sites survival, and see it as in their

    career interest to overcome local obstacles to transfer. Nor is the subsidiary workforce

    necessarily homogeneous. There may be differences of interest between high-skilled workers

    with core competences and lower-skilled workers with more generic competences, and

    transferred practices may differentially impact on such interests.

    Whether subsidiary actors deploy capabilities to resist or promote transfer will depend on how

    the practices affect existing interests. Resistance or contestation is likely to emerge under

    conditions of criticality, that is where the issue is seen as critical to the interests of actors in

    the subsidiary. For example, resistance may be expected where a transferred practice embodies

    institutional norms or requirements that disrupt accommodations seen as vital to the effective

    conduct of the economic function of the subsidiary, and hence to the economic security,

    rewards and career interests of groups and individual actors in the subsidiary.

    Where a transferred practice disrupts workforce interests but not those of managers (or vice

    versa), there is likely to be an internalization of the clash of rationalities within the host. In the

    area of HR&EP, it is more likely that interests in the subsidiary will be differentiated, with say

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    22/43

    employees and their representatives resisting transfer, while managers promote it. This may be

    manifested in managementworkforce conflict, or as Tempel et al. (2006) suggest, subsidiary

    managers may function as a Trojan horse for imported practices such as global performance

    management systems, working to neutralize institutional obstacles. Transferred practices may

    selectively disrupt interests of particular management groups, or particular workforce groups, or

    both. In such cases coalitions of support for and opposition to transfer may be complex and cut

    across the managementworkforce divide. However, where transfer disrupts a wide range of

    subsidiary interests, a subsidiary-wide oppositional coalition may emerge.

    Power, institutions and transfer outcomes

    These arguments are now synthesized into a model of transfer outcomes, in which

    constellations of institutional distance, macro- and micro-level power capabilities, and actors

    interests determine the fate of transferred practices.

    We argue, first, that there is a need to revise the Kostovian idea (e.g. Kostova, 1999) that MNCs

    operate between fairly fixed institutional entities, as implied by the notion of institutional

    distance. The impact of ID upon transfer is modified by the power of MNCs in two ways. In

    the first place, dominance effects, where they exist, smooth transfer by providing MNCs with

    abundant power over resources, power of process over the rules of the game, and power to

    manage meaning by reducing normative opposition to dominant-country practices in the host.

    In the second place, the power of MNCs as active rule-makers, engaging in institutional work

    to construct institutional variants or niches within the host setting, mitigates the constraining

    impact of institutional distance. In order to incorporate these considerations, we therefore

    propose that Kostovas notion of institutional distance, which we refer to as raw ID, be

    replaced by the concept of modified ID, (mID). Here, the predictions of our framework are

    significantly different from those of Kostovas.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    23/43

    Second, transfer outcomes depend on the specific configuration of power capabilities and

    interests of actors at different levels of the MNC. Where interests of subsidiary and HQ actors

    are broadly concordant, the power capabilities of the subsidiary are likely to be deployed in a

    mannersupportive of transfer, for example by removing or circumventing host institutional

    obstacles to transfer. However, where there are strong interests within the subsidiary in conflict

    with those of HQ, the outcome is likely to be an oppositionalstance. This does not necessarily

    entail overt resistance (cf. Oliver, 1991). Power capabilities may be deployed to resist, modify,

    neutralize, or quarantine the transferred practice through ritual observance that does not affect

    real practice. Which of these oppositional outcomes occurs is likely to depend on the

    homogeneity of interests within the subsidiary, and the power capabilities of the subsidiary (or

    at least of oppositional actors) relative to those of HQ.

    An outcome of ceremonial compliance in which nonconformity is masked by a faade of

    acquiescence (Oliver, 1991: 154) is likely where opposition is high due to a collision of

    normative/cognitive frameworks (e.g. concerning what will promote unit profitability in the

    subsidiary), but where subsidiary actors control of resources and/or processes is relatively low,

    precluding overt resistance.

    Alternatively, opposition may lead to adaptation or hybridization (e.g. Becker-Ritterspach,

    2009; Szulanski and Jensen, 2006) in which the practice acquires elements characteristic of the

    host setting. In some cases, this may make a practice more effective within the host, or allow it

    to be internalized by subsidiary employees. Survey evidence suggests that it is common for

    MNCs to disseminate practices by means of broad framework policies, with local adaptation

    being expected in HR&EP areas such as performance management, variable pay, and employee

    involvement (Edwards, P. et al., 2007). This may be termed functional hybridization.

    In other cases hybridization may divert a practice from its normal function and hence subvert

    HQs intention. For example, a supposedly standardized employee performance appraisal

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    24/43

    system in a US MNC operated with major variations in practice: thus in the German subsidiary

    the works council was able to reject individual assessment, minimize quantification, and reduce

    the scheme to occasional informal, unrecorded evaluations (Liberman and Torbiorn, 2000).

    Such resistive hybridization is likely where transfer disrupts internal accommodations and/or

    is seen as dysfunctional for subsidiary performance, and where subsidiary actors have sufficient

    power capabilities, such as interpretive control of local meaning frames.

    Third, the three dimensions of power are likely to affect transfer outcomes in different ways,

    other things being equal. Where a subsidiary has significantpower of resources, this is likely to

    facilitate a bargaining process in which the terms of entry of a transferred practice are

    negotiated between subsidiary and HQ. Where a subsidiary has significantpower of process, it

    may use it to influence how global policies or practices are designed within the MNC, for

    example by contributing to central policy-making bodies. This provides it with the opportunity

    to ensure that the transferred practice is from the start compatible with the cognitive/normative

    (or indeed regulatory) frames of the host. Finally, a subsidiary may be skilled in the

    management of meaning, whether in highlighting or concealing normative/cognitive

    discrepancies provoked by the transfer of a practice, or by mobilizing appropriate legitimatory

    discourses within the micro-institutional sphere of the MNC. This power may affect transfer

    outcomes in different ways. Where the subsidiarys stance is oppositional, it may evoke host

    macro-institutional impediments, drawing on its skilled interpretation of institutions-in-

    practice. Equally, where its other power capabilities are relatively weak, it may use its skills in

    managing meaning to construct the ceremonial aspects of the practice without impinging on

    the subsidiarys core activity. Where the subsidiarys stance is supportive of transfer, the power

    of meaning may be brought to bear to secure the internalization (Kostova, 1999) of transferred

    practices.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    25/43

    Returning to the outcome parameters outlined in the introduction, we can synthesize the above

    arguments (see table 2) in terms of typical scenarios, based on differentiation of functionality,

    internalization, adaptation and directionality. The table indicates that the conditions most

    conducive for successful transfer in which functional practices are internalized are where: HQ

    actively wants to transfer practices, ID is low, dominance effects are high, institutional space is

    high, HQs power capabilities are relatively strong, HQ and subsidiary interests are concordant

    and the interests of subsidiary actors are homogeneous (model 1). To take a stylized example, a

    US business services firm i.e. an MNC from the hegemonic business system, in a sector in

    which that business system is internationally dominant transfers a performance appraisal

    system to its professional employees in its non-unionized Irish subsidiary as part of the global

    dissemination of standardized HR policies. Many of the employees have worked for American

    firms before US MNCs predominate among foreign employers in Ireland and have studied

    or worked in the US. Their cognitive/normative frames are attuned to American performance-

    management systems, especially since there is a strong values-based corporate culture, and

    there are unlikely to be discordant interests with regards to the policy, so the practice is likely to

    be easily internalized. There are few macro-institutional constraints to the introduction of such

    policies and few variant constraints stemming e.g. from the presence of trade unions.

    This can be contrasted with five other scenarios. As ID increases and capabilities, particularly

    resources, controlled by the subsidiary grow, the prospect of transfer taking the form of

    functional hybridization increases (model 2). To illustrate, a US electronics MNC attempts to

    transfer a performance-related pay system to the more constrained and institutionally distant

    context of Germany.4 There is a perceived disjunction between the policy and

    cognitive/normative frames of employees, i.e. the cross-institutional transfer reveals the

    cognitive/normative underpinnings of the system. The subsidiary is large, successful and

    powerful, giving it power over resources with which to negotiate with HQ a modification of the

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    26/43

    practice for example, by reducing the amount of pay at risk, to make it more acceptable within

    the host context (e.g. Tempel et al., 2006).

    Where dominance effects weaken, institutional space is more constrained, the subsidiary

    possesses significant power of resources and process relative to HQ, and has divergent interests

    from HQ, then the likelihood of resistive hybridization and low internalization rises (model 3).

    For example, Lindholm et al. (1999) show how performance appraisal systems in Nordic MNCs

    in China were subverted because the systems provoked extensive clashes with

    cognitive/normative frames, e.g. with regards to the priority given to performance rather than

    seniority, and issues around loss of face and around managerial authority in setting targets.

    If dominance effects are absent, ID is high, and subsidiary interests clash with HQs, transfer

    may fail altogether (model 4). To illustrate, a British MNC seeks to internationalize a policy of

    outsourcing support functions to reduce labour costs. It pressurizes foreign subsidiaries where

    the ratio of outsourced workers to internal employees is significantly lower than in UK

    domestic operations. This is the case in the German subsidiary, one of the largest in the

    company and with important production facilities for key products. Subsidiary managers are

    sceptical as to the efficiency of outsourcing and the HR manager uses his detailed knowledge of

    German employment law to circumvent the need to outsource functions (e.g. Tempel, 2002).

    Where institutional space is moderate, the subsidiary is not particularly powerful (in resource or

    process terms) in relation to HQ, and has quite different interests to actors at HQ, the prospects

    for ceremonial adoption are at their highest (model 5). To take a stylized example, a British

    MNC attempts to internationalize its comprehensive diversity management practices. In its

    medium-sized production facilities in Germany, there is considerable scepticism among

    managers and primarily male employees as to the business case for diversity management.

    Lacking power of resources or process to openly block HQ practices, managers go through the

    motions of introducing diversity management measures, for example by organizing social

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    27/43

    events under the label of diversity management, but do not implement real changes in

    recruitment processes to encourage more female applicants or introduce diversity awareness

    training for employees.

    Finally, where interests are concordant and where the subsidiarys power capabilities are

    considerable - especially when its institutional embeddedness allows it to develop scarce

    resources of value to the wider MNC - conditions exist for reverse transfer (model 6). That is

    to say, practices operating in the subsidiary are transferred to headquarters (Edwards and

    Ferner, 2004). These conditions are heightened in situations of reverse dominance, that is

    where the subsidiarys host system is more dominant than the MNCs parent system. For

    example, a German chemical company developed a global system of bonus pay for executives

    that was modelled closely on schemes already developed in the US subsidiary of the company

    (Ferner and Varul, 2000).

    These models are not, of course, exhaustive: other outcomes are possible; and the same transfer

    outcome may be obtained through different combinations of variables. But they illustrate the

    heuristic value of the approach. It should be noted that a certain degree of interaction of

    explanatory variables is likely. For example, MNCs from dominant parent countries are likely

    to be able to influence subnational variety because of their greater capacity for rule-making

    rather than mere rule-taking behaviour.

    [Table 2 about here]

    Conclusion

    This paper has argued for a revision of the Kostovian approach to practice transfer in MNCs in

    two key respects: systematically incorporating actors power capabilities, and taking account of

    how power problematizes ID by rendering it more susceptible to the purposive action of MNC

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    28/43

    actors. We have argued for an analysis of power that incorporates both macro-institutional and

    micro-institutional capabilities of MNC actors in which these are able to a greater or lesser

    extent to manipulate and construct elements of the institutional settings in which they operate.

    The implications of the argument are methodological as well as conceptual. First, there is a

    need to develop credible measures of the variables in the model. The concept of mID implies

    the need to assess dominance effects, for example, and these will vary according to the pairs of

    parent and host business systems in play; dominance may also vary e.g. by sector. Much work

    needs to be done on measuring notions such as institutional space, and to map the dimensions

    that characterize institutional variants. This has to be accomplished at a disaggregated level:

    notions of country institutional profile may be too crude where MNCs power allows them to

    construct niche institutional micro-climates. One of the most difficult tasks is to operationalize

    actors power capabilities and to empirically assess different levels of capabilities in relation to

    resource, process and meaning. Moreover, empirical tools capable of identifying and

    distinguishing interests are needed, a task complicated by the fact that while some underlying

    interests may be long-term and durable for example, around organizational survival others

    may well be issue-specific, constructed anew around each instance of transfer.

    These points suggest a critical role for in-depth case studies. They allow deeper exploration

    both of the process of transfer and of how transferred practices are implemented in the routine

    life of the subsidiary. They are more suited than surveys to developing nuanced

    operationalizations and unpicking the complexities of power, how different kinds of power

    capabilities are deployed by different actors in the transfer process, and how configurations of

    interests are constructed around different transfer cases. They are more appropriate for

    exploring in depth the way transferred practices operate in reality.

    Finally, there is the question of the generalizability of these arguments to other areas of

    management activity. Inasmuch as transfer provokes challenges to existing modes of action and

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    29/43

    to institutional frameworks, much of the same processes of power are likely to be observed in

    other areas. The cross-national transfer of technical know-how, for example, exposes

    underlying cognitive assumptions about how the production of knowledge and development of

    products should be organized (e.g. Lam, 1997; Szulanski and Jensen, 2006). It is also likely to

    create conflicts of interest over control of knowledge as a resource, or concerns about the

    impact of transferred knowledge on the structuring of activities and actors roles in the recipient

    unit. Beyond that, however, HR&EP may have distinctive characteristics, relating partly to the

    structured antagonisms between capital and labour (Edwards, 1986). More immediately, as a

    downstream business activity, HR&EP is particularly prone to the normative principles that

    may be at odds with the prescriptions of upstream strategy, increasing the space for actors to

    exploit micro-institutional ambiguities between, for instance, directives on growth, profitability

    or efficiency on the one hand, and principles of employee management on the other.

    Funding statement

    This research was supported by funding from the Economic & Social Research Council, grant

    numbers R000-23-8350 and RES-000-230305.

    Notes

    According to Scopus, the number of citations for three of Kostovas articles concerning

    transfer (as at 15th September 2011) are as follows: Kostova, 1999: 321; Kostova and Zaheer,

    1999: 329; Kostova and Roth, 2002: 281.

    2 The term capabilities is preferred to resources since power over resources constitutes only

    one dimension of power (one that is the focus of resource-based views of power that

    predominate in the business literature).

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    30/43

    3 Perceptions of profitability in an MNC can be shaped by how costs are allocated and internal

    pricing systems are designed by HQ actors.

    4 We do not wish to imply that US MNCs invariably exhibit dominance. Although there may be

    a general dominance effect deriving from the status of US firms in the world economy, more

    specific aspects of dominance may depend on sectoral factors.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    31/43

    References

    Almond P (2011) The sub-national embeddedness of multinational corporations.Human

    Relations 64(4): 531-51.

    Almond P and Ferner A (eds) (2006)American Multinationals in Europe: Managing

    Employment Relations Across National Borders. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Almond P, Muller-Camen M, Collings D and Quintanilla J (2006) Pay and Performance. In:

    Almond P and Ferner A (eds),American Multinationals in Europe: Managing

    Employment Relations Across National Borders. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 119-

    45.

    Andersson U and Forsgren M (1996) Subsidiary embeddedness and control in the multinational

    corporation.International Business Review 5(5): 487-508.

    Andersson U and Holm U (eds) (2010)Managing the Contemporary Multinational.

    Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Becker-Ritterspach F (2009)Hybridization of MNE Subsidiaries. Basingstoke: Palgrave

    Macmillan.

    Blanger J, Berggren C, Bjrkman T and Khler C (1999)Being Local Worldwide: ABB and

    the Challenge of Global Management. Ithaca: ILR Press.

    Blanger J and Edwards P (2006) Towards a political economy framework: TNCs as national

    and international players. In: Ferner A, Quintanilla J and Snchez-Runde C

    Multinationals, Institutions and the Construction of Transnational Practices.

    Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 24-52.

    Bouquet C and Birkinshaw J (2008) Managing power in the multinational corporation: How

    low-power actors gain influence.Journal of Management34(3): 477-508.

    Boxall P and Purcell J (2011) Strategy and Human Resource Management. Basingstoke:

    Palgrave Macmillan.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    32/43

    Campbell J L (2004)Institutional Change and Globalization. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton

    University Press.

    Clemens ES and Cook JM (1999) Politics and Institutionalism: Explaining Durability and

    Change.Annual Review of Sociology 25: 441-66.

    Colling T, Gunnigle P, Quintanilla J and Tempel A (2006) Collective representation and

    participation. In: Almond P and Ferner A (eds)American Multinationals in Europe.

    Oxford: Oxford University Press, 95118.

    Crouch C (2005) Capitalist Diversity and Change: Recombinant Governance and Institutional

    Entrepreneurs. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Crouch C, Schrder M and Voelzkow H (2009) Regional and sectoral varieties of capitalism.

    Economy and Society 38(4): 654-78.

    Delmestri G (2009) Institutional Streams, Logics, and Fields.Research in the Sociology of

    Organizations 27: 115-44.

    DeVos T (1981) US Multinationals and Worker Participation in Management. The American

    experience in the European Community. London: Aldwych.

    Djelic M-L and Quack S (eds) (2003) Globalization and institutions - Redefining the rules of

    the economic game. London: Edward Elgar.

    Drrenbcher C and Gammelgaard J (2010) Multinational corporations, inter-organizational

    networks and subsidiary charter removals.Journal of World Business 45(2): 206-16.

    Drrenbcher C and Gammelgaard J (2011) Subsidiary power in multinational corporations: the

    subtle role of micro-political bargaining power. Critical Perspectives on International

    Business 7(1): 30-47.

    Drrenbcher C and Geppert M (2009a) A Micro-political Perspective on Subsidiary Initiative-

    taking: Evidence from German-owned Subsidiaries in France.European Management

    Journal27(2): 100-12.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    33/43

    Drrenbcher C and Geppert M (2009b) Micro-political Games in the Multinational

    Corporation: The Case of Mandate Change.Management Revue 20(4): 373-391.

    Drrenbcher C and Geppert M (eds) (2011)Politics and Power in the International

    Corporation: The role of institutions, interests and identities. Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press.

    Edwards P (1986) Conflict at Work: A Materialist Analysis of Workplace Relations. Oxford:

    Blackwell.

    Edwards T and Ferner A (2004) Multinationals, reverse diffusion and national business

    systems.Management International Review Special issue (1/2004): 49-79.

    Edwards P and Blanger J (2009) The MNC as a contested terrain. In: Collinson S and Morgan

    G (eds) The Multinational Firm. Oxford: Wiley, 193-216.

    Edwards P, Edwards T, Ferner A, Marginson P and Tregaskis O (2007) Employment Practices

    of MNCs in Organisational Context: A Large-Scale Survey. Available at:

    http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/projects/mncemployment/conference_papers/fu

    ll_report_july.pdf.

    Edwards T, Colling T and Ferner A (2007) Conceptual approaches to the transfer of

    employment practices in multinational companies: an integrated approach.Human

    Resource Management Journal17(3): 201-17.

    Edwards T and Ferner A (2004) Multinationals, reverse diffusion and national business

    systems.Management International Review Special issue (1/2004): 49-79.

    Egelhoff W (2010) Evaluating the role of parent HQ in a contemporary MNC. In: Andersson U

    and Holm U (eds)Managing the Contemporary Multinational. Cheltenham: Edward

    Elgar, 106-22.

    http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/projects/mncemployment/conference_papers/full_report_july.pdfhttp://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/projects/mncemployment/conference_papers/full_report_july.pdfhttp://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/projects/mncemployment/conference_papers/full_report_july.pdfhttp://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/projects/mncemployment/conference_papers/full_report_july.pdfhttp://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/projects/mncemployment/conference_papers/full_report_july.pdf
  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    34/43

    Erkama N and Vaara E (2010) Struggles over Legitimacy in Global Organizational

    Restructuring: A Rhetorical Perspective on Legitimation Strategies and Dynamics in a

    Shutdown Case. Organisation Studies 31(7): 813-39.

    Evans P and Lorange P (1989) The Two Logics Behind Human Resource Management. In:

    Evans P, Doz Y and Laurent A (eds)Human Resource Management in International

    Firms. Change, Globalization, Innovation. Basingstoke: Macmillan, 144-61.

    Ferner A (2000) The underpinnings of "bureaucratic" control systems: HRM in European

    multinationals.Journal of Management Studies 37(4): 521-40.

    Ferner A, Almond P and Colling T (2005) Institutional theory and the cross-national transfer of

    employment policy: the case of 'workforce diversity' in US multinationals.Journal of

    International Business Studies 36(3): 304-21.

    Ferner A and Edwards P (1995) Power and the diffusion of organizational change within

    multinational enterprises.European Journal of Industrial Relations 1(2): 229-57.

    Ferner A and Tempel A (2006) Multinationals and National Business Systems: A Power and

    Institutions Perspective. In: Ferner A and Almond P (eds)American Multinationals in

    Europe. Managing Employment Relations Across National Borders, Oxford: OUP, 10-

    33.

    Ferner A and Varul M Zick (2000) Vanguard subsidiaries and the diffusion of new practices:

    a case study of German multinationals.British Journal of Industrial Relations 38(1):

    115-40.

    Geppert M and Drrenbcher C (2011) Politics and Power in the Multinational Corporation: An

    introduction. In: Drrenbcher C and Geppert M (eds)Politics and Power in the

    International Corporation: The role of institutions, interests and identities. Cambridge:

    Cambridge University Press, 1-38.

    Gramsci A (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks. New York: International Publishers.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    35/43

    Greenwood R and Hinings CR (1996) Understanding radical organizational change. Bringing

    together the old and the new institutionalism.Academy of Management Review 21(4):

    1022-1054.

    Gunnigle P, Collings DG and Morley MJ (2006)Accommodating global capitalism? Statepolicy and industrial relations in American MNCs in Ireland. In: Ferner A, Quintanilla J

    and Sanchez-Runde C (eds)Multinationals and the Construction of Transnational

    Practices: Convergence and Diversity in the Global Economy, Basingstoke: Palgrave

    Macmillan, 86-108.

    Hall P and Soskice D (2001) An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism. In: Hall P and

    Soskice D Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative

    Advantage. Oxford: OUP, 1-70.

    Hardy C (1996) Understanding Power: Bringing about Strategic Change.British Journal of

    Management7(S1), 3-16.

    Knight J (1992)Institutions and Social Conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Kostova T (1999) Transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: A contextual

    perspective.Academy of Management Review 24(2): 308-24.

    Kostova T and Roth K (2002) Adoption of an organizational practice by subsidiaries of

    multinational corporations: institutional and relational effects.Academy of Management

    Journal35(1): 215-33.

    Kostova T, Roth K and Dacin M (2008) Institutional Theory in the Study of MNCs: A Critique

    and New Directions. Academy of Management Review 33(4): 994-1007.

    Kostova T and Zaheer S (1999) Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: the

    case of the multinational enterprise.Academy of Management Review 24(1): 64-81.

    Kotthoff H (1994)Betriebsrte und Brgerstatus: Wandel und Kontinuitt betrieblicher

    Mitbestimmung. Munich: Hampp.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    36/43

    Kristensen P H and Zeitlin J (2005)Local Players in Global Games: The strategic constitution

    of a multinational corporation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Lado A and Wilson M (1994) Human resource systems and sustained competitive advantage: a

    competency-based perspective.Academy of Management Review 19(4): 699-728.

    Lam A (1997) Embedded firms, embedded knowledge. Organization Studies 18(6): 973-96.

    Lane C and Wood G (2009) Capitalist diversity and diversity within capitalism.Economy and

    Society 38(4): 531-51.

    Lawrence T (2008) Power, Institutions and Organizations. In: Greenwood R, Oliver C, Sahlin K

    and Suddaby R (eds) The Sage Handbook of Organizational Institutionalism. Los

    Angeles: Sage, 170-97.

    Lawrence T and Suddaby R (2006) Institutions and Institutional work. In: Clegg SR, Hardy C,

    Lawrence T and Nord W (eds)Handbook of Organization Studies, 2nd Edition.

    London: Sage: 215-54.

    Levy D L (2008) Political Contestation in Global Production Networks.Academy of

    Management Review 33(4): 94363.

    Levy D L and Egan D (2003) A Neo-Gramscian Approach to Corporate Political Strategy:

    Conflict and Accommodation in the Climate Change Negotiations.Journal of

    Management Studies 40(4): 803-29.

    Liberman L and Torbiorn I (2000) 'Variances in staff-related management practices at eight

    European country subsidiaries of a global firm',International Journal of Human

    Resource Management11(1): 37-59.

    Lindholm N, Tahvanainen M and Bjrkman I (1999) Performance appraisal of host country

    employees: Western MNCs in China. In: Brewster C and Harris H (eds)International

    HRM: Contemporary issues in Europe. London: Routledge, 143-59.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    37/43

    Lounsbury M (2003) The Problem of Order Revisited: Towards a Critical Institutional

    Perspective. In: Westwood R and Clegg SDebating Organization: Point-Counterpoint

    in Organization Studies. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing, 210-19.

    Lukes S (1975)Power: A Radical View. London: Palgrave-Macmillan.

    Lukes S (2005)Power: A Radical View. (2nd edition.) London: Palgrave-Macmillan.

    Morgan G (2009) Globalization, Multinationals and Institutional Diversity.Economy and

    Society 38(4): 580-605.

    Morgan G (2011) Reflections on the macro-politics of micro-politics. In: Drrenbcher C and

    Geppert M (eds) Politics and Power in the International Corporation: The role of

    institutions, interests and identities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 415-36.

    Morgan G and Kristensen PH (2006) The contested space of multinationals: Varieties of

    institutionalism, varieties of capitalism.Human Relations 59(11): 1467-90.

    Morgan G, Kelly B, Sharpe D and Whitley R (2003) Global Managers and Japanese

    Multinationals,International Journal of Human Resource Management14(3): 309-407.

    Oliver C (1991) Strategic responses to institutional processes.Academy of Management Review

    16(1): 145-79.

    Phillips N, Tracey P and Karra N (2009) Rethinking Institutional Distance: Strengthening the

    Tie Between New Institutional Theory and International Management. Strategic

    Organization 7(3): 339-48.

    Pudelko M and Harzing Anne-Wil K (2007) Country-of-Origin, Localization or Dominance

    Effects? An empirical investigation of HRM practices in foreign subsidiaries.Human

    Resource Management46(4): 535-59.

    Rosenzweig P and Nohria N (1994) Influences on human resource management practices in

    multinational corporations.Journal of International Business Studies 25(2): 229-51.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    38/43

    Saka A (2002) Institutional Limits to the Internalization of Work Systems: A Comparative

    Study of Three Japanese MNCs in the UK.European Journal of Industrial Relations

    8(3): 251-75.

    Schwartz H (2009) Subprime Nation: American Power, Global Capital and the Housing

    Bubble. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Scott W Richard (2008)Institutions and Organizations, Thousand Oaks: Sage.

    Sell SK (2000) Big Business and the New Trade Agreements. In: Stubbs R and Underhill G

    (eds) Political Economy and the Changing Global Order, Don Mills, Ontario: Oxford

    University Press: 174-83.

    Seo M G and Creed WED (2002) Institutional contradictions, praxis, and institutional change:

    A dialectical perspective.Academy of Management Review 27(2): 222-47.

    Singe I and Croucher R (2005) US Multi-Nationals and the German Industrial Relations

    System.Management Revue 16(1): 123-37.

    Sklair Leslie (2001) The Transnational Capitalist Class.Oxford: Blackwell.

    Smith C and Meiskins P (1995) System, Society and Dominance Effects in Cross-National

    Organisational Analysis. 'Work, Employment and Society 9(2): 241-67.

    Sorge A and Rothe K (2011) Resource dependence and construction, and macro- and micro-

    politics in transnational enterprises and alliances: the case of jet engine manufacturers in

    Germany. In: Drrenbcher and Geppert (eds)Politics and Power in the International

    Corporation: The role of institutions, interests and identities. Cambridge: Cambridge

    University Press, 41-70.

    Stinchcombe AL (1997) On the virtues of the old institutionalism.Annual Review of Sociology

    23: 1-18.

    Streeck W and Thelen K (2005)Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political

    Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    39/43

    Suddaby R and Greenwood R (2005) Rhetorical Strategies of Legitimacy.Administrative

    Science Quarterly 50(1): 35-67.

    Szulanski G (1996) Exploring Internal Stickiness: Impediments to the Transfer of Best Practice

    within the Firm. Strategic Management Journal17(Winter Special Issue): 27-43.

    Szulanski G and Jensen R (2006) Presumptive adaptation and the effectiveness of knowledge

    transfer. Strategic Management Journal27(10): 937-57.

    Tempel A (2002) Multinational companies, institutional environments and the diffusion of

    industrial relations practices. In: Mike Geppert, Dirk Matten and Karen Williams (eds),

    Challenges for European Management in a European Context, London: Palgrave, 143-

    64.

    Tempel A and Walgenbach P (2007) Global Standardization of Organizational Forms and

    Management Practices? What New Institutionalism and the Business Systems Approach

    Can Learn From Each Other.Journal of Management Studies 44(1): 1-24.

    Tempel A, Edwards T, Ferner A, Muller-Camen M and Wchter H (2006) Subsidiary

    Responses to Institutional Duality: Collective Representation in US Multinationals in

    Britain and Germany.Human Relations 59(11): 1543-70.

    Thelen K (2009) Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. British Journal of

    Industrial Relations 47(3): 471-98.

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    40/43

    Table 1a.Power capabilities of HQ actors

    Level Kind of power capability

    Power of resources Power of processes Power of meaning

    Macro-institutional -global

    Dominance effects (Smith and Meiksins, 1995) Influence over systemic decision-making rules (e.g.Levy and Egan, 2003; Sell, 2000)

    Notions of globalization, competitiveness,markets etc. provide a legitimizing frame

    (Campbell, 2004) for HQ actions

    Macro-institutional -

    national

    Lobbying capabilities (e.g. DeVos, 1981)

    Ability to influence sovereign states through

    investment choices (direct, indirect)

    Involvement in regulatory and normative bodies e.g.

    employers associations

    Mobilization of alternative cognitive/normative

    frameworks

    Macro-institutional

    subnational

    Influence over subnational governance actors such as

    local authorities and development agencies

    (decisions to invest and reinvest in locality) leading

    to sub-national variants within host spaces

    Embeddedness in local governance networks e.g. for

    skills generation (e.g. Almond, 2011)

    Creation of variant cognitive and normative frames,

    e.g. concerning the role of skills within the local

    labour market (e.g. Crouch et al., 2009)

    Micro-institutional Material resources:

    Control of sanctions and rewards for subsidiaries investment, know-how

    Control of individuals recruitment, career andrewards (e.g. Drrenbcher and Geppert, 2009a)

    Formal authority to define decision-making

    structures and rules; power to determine which actorsare involved in rule-making

    Control of cognitive frames e.g. through mission,

    vision and value statements

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    41/43

    Table 1b. Power capabilities of subsidiary actors

    Level Kind of power capability

    Power of resources Power of processes Power of meaning

    Macro-institutional -global

    -- -- --

    Macro-institutional -

    national

    Rights deriving from host regulatory framework, e.g.

    consultation and codetermination

    Privileged access to institutional decision-makers

    (Drrenbcher and Gammelgaard, 2010)

    Interpretative claims with regards to regulatory,

    cognitive and normative frames

    Macro-institutional

    subnational

    Mobilization of action networks to enhance

    performance/ resist HQ impositions regional tradeunion bodies

    Including resources derived from embeddedness in

    local production networks

    Embeddedness links with subnational governance

    actors

    Links into knowledge and skills networks (e.g.

    Kristensen and Zeitlin, 2005) that shape local

    institutional arrangements

    Micro-institutional Material resources:

    Leverage from economic performance (e.g.

    profitability, % of global output/revenue/profits)

    Delegated formal authority e.g. stemming from

    corporate mandates

    Challenges to HQ agendas

    Manipulation of rival claims to legitimacy

    Capacity to challenge on basis of macro-institutional

    interpretations of institutions-in-practice

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    42/43

    TABLE 2 Predicted outcomes of power and institutional configurations

    Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

    HQ desire to transfer H H H H H H

    mID (modified institutional distance)

    raw institutional distance L-M H L-H H L-H L-M

    dominance effects H-M H M-L L L-H rev H-Minstitutional space (subnational variety) H H L L M L-H

    subsidiary power capabilities M-Hr, p Hr, p, m Hr, m Hr Lr, pHm Hr

    ratio of HQ:subsidiary power resources

    macro-institutional H H-M M-L M-L H M-L

    micro-institutional H H-M M-L M-L H M-L

    Interest divergence HQ/subsidiary L L H H H L

    Interest homogeneity in subsidiary H H L L H H

    TRANSFER OUTCOME Successfultransfer, high

    internalization

    Functional

    hybridization,

    highinternalization

    Resistive

    hybridization,

    lowinternalization

    Failed transfer Ceremonial or

    ritual

    compliance,low

    internalization

    Reverse

    transfer

    H = high, M = medium, L = low; note: where a range of values is given (e.g. L-H) the specific outcome is insensitive to variations in the input.

    rev = reverse dominance effects, i.e. the host business system is dominant in relation to the parent system

    r= resource power; p = process power; m = meaning power

  • 8/2/2019 Ferner Power

    43/43

    Corresponding author:

    Anthony Ferner

    Leicester Business School

    De Montfort University

    Leicester

    LE1 9BH

    United Kingdom

    [email protected]

    Other authors

    Tony Edwards

    Department of Management

    King's College LondonLondon

    United Kingdom

    [email protected]

    Anne Tempel

    Faculty of Business Studies and Economics

    University of Dsseldorf

    Universittsstrasse 1

    D-40225 Dsseldorf

    Germany

    [email protected]